The$return$of$industrial$policy$on$the$African$ continent$and$the$drivers$of$this$revival$

Similar documents
High Level Seminar on the Creative Economy and Copyright as Pathways to Sustainable Development. UN-ESCAP/ WIPO, Bangkok December 6, 2017

Higher Education for Science, Technology and Innovation. Accelerating Africa s Aspirations. Communique. Kigali, Rwanda.

Expert Group Meeting on

Technology transfer and development: implications of four case studies Session 2

ORCADE. Organisation pour le Renforcement des Capacités de Développement Tel: BP 675 Ouagadougou 09 Burkina Faso

Economic and Social Council

demonstrator approach real market conditions would be useful to provide a unified partner search instrument for the CIP programme

Commission on science and Technology for Development. Ninth Session Geneva, May2006

Technology and Competitiveness in Vietnam

Industrial Policy Supports

NEW INDUSTRIAL POLICY

Et Extension from an innovation systems perspective

Innovation in Europe: Where s it going? How does it happen? Stephen Roper Aston Business School, Birmingham, UK

BASED ECONOMIES. Nicholas S. Vonortas

Globalizing IPR Protection: How Important Might RTAs Be?

Case Study Disclaimer. Participants Case Studies

THE INTERNATIONAL COMPETITIVENESS OF ECONOMIES IN TRANSITION THE UNTAPPED POTENTIAL: A CHALLENGE FOR BUSINESS AND GOVERNMENT BELARUS

Creative Industries: The Next Phase

THE IMPLICATIONS OF THE KNOWLEDGE-BASED ECONOMY FOR FUTURE SCIENCE AND TECHNOLOGY POLICIES

OECD Science, Technology and Industry Outlook 2008: Highlights

Learning Lessons Abroad on Funding Research and Innovation. 29 April 2016

Agenda Item 4: Transport Strategy: Vision and Objectives

The Design Economy. The value of design to the UK. Executive summary

Executive Summary World Robotics 2018 Industrial Robots

TRANSFORMATION INTO A KNOWLEDGE-BASED ECONOMY: THE MALAYSIAN EXPERIENCE

26-27 October Robots, Industrialization and Industrial Policy. Paper submitted by. Jorge MAYER Senior Economic Affairs Officer UNCTAD

WIPO REGIONAL SEMINAR ON SUPPORT SERVICES FOR INVENTORS, VALUATION AND COMMERCIALIZATION OF INVENTIONS AND RESEARCH RESULTS

Inclusively Creative

Trump s Protectionism: A Great Leap Backward. James Petras. US Presidents, European leaders and their academic spokespeople have attributed

COUNCIL OF THE EUROPEAN UNION. Brussels, 9 December 2008 (16.12) (OR. fr) 16767/08 RECH 410 COMPET 550

FINLAND. The use of different types of policy instruments; and/or Attention or support given to particular S&T policy areas.

Reputation enhanced by innovation - Call for proposals in module 3

Hellenic Technology Clusters Initiative

ASEAN: A Growth Centre in the Global Economy

NEW ZEALAND. Evaluation of the Public Good Science Fund An Overview.

Japan Lagging in Scientific Research

MSMES: OPPORTUNITIES AND CHALLENGES FOR THE SDG AGENDA

Seoul Initiative on the 4 th Industrial Revolution

2010/3 Science and technology for development. The Economic and Social Council,

Introduction to the SMEs Division of WIPO

NO SUCH THING AS A COMMODITY

Werner Wobbe. Employed at the European Commission, Directorate General Research and Innovation

Disruptive SBC strategies for the future of Africa

DRAFT. "The potential opportunities and challenges for SMEs in the context of the European Trade Policy:

An Essential Health and Biomedical R&D Treaty

Science, Technology & Innovation Policy Review - the Asian experience. Yu Wing Yin University of Bielefeld

Knowledge-Oriented Diversification Strategies: Policy Options for Transition Economies

Industrial Policy Action Plan (IPAP) Industrial Policy Chief Directorate

Infrastructure services for private sector development (P) Project

THE IMPACT OF SCIENCE DISCUSSION PAPER

Fostering SME innovation through cross-border cooperation

Technology Platforms: champions to leverage knowledge for growth

STATE ADVANCED MANUFACTURING POLICIES AND PROGRAMS. As at February 2018

A Dynamic Analysis of Internationalization in the Solar Energy Sector: The Co-Evolution of TIS in Germany and China

Science, technology and engineering for innovation and capacity-building in education and research UNCTAD Wednesday, 28 November 2007

The ICT industry as driver for competition, investment, growth and jobs if we make the right choices

New and Emerging Issues Interface to Science Policy

Building an enterprise-centred innovation system

Horizon 2020 Towards a Common Strategic Framework for EU Research and Innovation Funding

BISMILLAHIR RAHMANIR RAHIM, Hon ble Chief Guest Dr. Atiur Rahman, Governor, Bangladesh Bank;

THE FUTURE OF MANUFACTURING-LED DEVELOPMENT

Borderland Ecosystems Mapping the Informal Economy

PROJECT IMPLEMENTATION PROPOSAL INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY (IP) AND INFORMAL ECONOMY (RECOMMENDATION 34)

Unit 1: The Economic Fundamentals Weeks How does scarcity impact the decisions individuals and societies must make?

Research on Catch-up Oriented Industrial Technological Capabilities Growth in Developing Countries

Academic Vocabulary Test 1:

The Technology Innovation Agency (TIA): Mobilising resources for R&D led

Expanding and positioning Uganda s technical capabilities for the oil and gas industry

BUILDING KNOWLEDGE CAPACITY FOR SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT IN THE ARAB WORLD

OECD-INADEM Workshop on

COMPETITIVNESS, INNOVATION AND GROWTH: THE CASE OF MACEDONIA

GROWTH-STRATEGY FOR THE ENGINEERING INDUSTRY TO ACHIEVE RAPID INDUSTRIALIZATION AND ECONOMIC GROWTH

FRAMEWORK ACT ON MARINE FISHERY DEVELOPMENT. [Enforcement Date: Nov. 28, 2009] [Act No. 9717, May 27, 2009, Other Laws and Regulations Amended]

Enforcement of Intellectual Property Rights Frequently Asked Questions

RFP No. 794/18/10/2017. Research Design and Implementation Requirements: Centres of Competence Research Project

The Role of the Intellectual Property Office

MEXICO 2030 BEFORE THE FOURTH INDUSTRIAL REVOLUTION: PROPOSALS FOR PRODUCTIVITY, GROWTH AND SOCIAL INCLUSION. Executive Summary

Challenges for the New Cohesion Policy nd joint EU Cohesion Policy Conference

5 TH MANAGEMENT SEMINARS FOR HEADS OF NATIONAL STATISTICAL OFFICES (NSO) IN ASIA AND THE PACIFIC SEPTEMBER 2006, DAEJEON, REPUBLIC OF KOREA

2050 Edinburgh City Vision. One Year On

Regional innovation strategies: the Apulian experience and the role of ARTI, the Regional Agency for Technology and Innovation

April Promoting the export competitiveness of SMEs

Making Sense of Science

SBIR/STTR & Commercialization of University Innovations

TechVelopment: Approach and Narrative

Implementation of the integrated emerging contractor development model: Towards enhanced competition for small construction firms

National Agreement on the Circular Economy. Letter of intent to develop transition agendas for the Circular Economy together

New Paradigm of Korean Economy: To be More Creative and Innovative

PROMOTING QUALITY AND STANDARDS

RIS3 from Strategic Orientations towards Policy Implementation: The Challenges Claire NAUWELAERS Independent expert in STI policy

Opening Speech by Commissioner Phil Hogan at EU Conference

The actors in the research system are led by the following principles:

Draft executive summaries to target groups on industrial energy efficiency and material substitution in carbonintensive

Under the Patronage of His Highness Sayyid Faisal bin Ali Al Said Minister for National Heritage and Culture

CHAPTER TWENTY COOPERATION. The objective of this Chapter is to facilitate the establishment of close cooperation aimed, inter alia, at:

15890/14 MVG/cb 1 DG G 3 C

ACP/84/047/02 Final Cape Town, 28 July 2002 PAHD Dept. CAPE TOWN DECLARATION ON RESEARCH FOR SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT

From the bottom-up: Firm capabilities and the inbetween

BOOK REVIEWS. Technological Superpower China

Review of the University vision, ambition and strategy January 2016 Sir David Bell KCB, Vice-Chancellor

Transcription:

The$return$of$industrial$policy$on$the$African$ continent$and$the$drivers$of$this$revival$ Christopher Cramer SOAS, University of London Nicolas Meisel Agence Française de Développement (AFD) Issues Papers on Structural Transformation and Industrial Policy No. 001-2016 Ethiopian Development Research Institute (EDRI) In Partnership with: School of Oriental and African Studies, University of London & Agence Française de Développement (AFD) March 2016 Copyright 2016 Ethiopian Development Research Institute; School of Oriental and African Studies, University of London; Agence Française de Développement

The return of industrial policy on the African continent and the drivers of this revival Christopher*Cramer* * Nicolas*Meisel* Industrial policy that is of relevance to low6income countries in Africa has made something of a comeback lately. The UNECA s annual report in 2014 argued that turning impressive African growth rates in recent years into lasting structural transformation requires credible industrial policies and supportive institutions. RenownedinternationaleconomistsandformerchiefeconomistsoftheWorldBank JosephStiglitzandJustinLinbothargueforindustrialpolicyinAfrica.Manyothers have jumped on the industrial policy bandwagon, despite the fact that for a long time, until very recently, advocates of industrial policy were regarded by mainstreameconomistsaspariahs. Yetitremainsunclearexactlywhatindustrialpolicyisorshouldbe,andwhatmakes itworkinsomecontextsandfailinothers.thisbriefdefinesthecoreofindustrial policy and explains why it is necessary. It also shows, however, that working out exactly how to implement an industrial policy that produces desired outcomes is morechallengingthananytechnicalortextbookblueprintcancapture. There are many definitions of industrial policy. But most are variants on a theme, namely, such policy involves government intervention in the economy to direct resources to and support the expansion of manufacturing in order to accelerate structural change in the economy. Or as one detailed definition states, industrial policyis: anytypeofselectiveinterventionorgovernmentpolicythatattemptsto alter the structure of production toward sectors that are expected to offer better prospectsforeconomicgrowththanwouldoccurintheabsenceofsuchintervention, i.e.,inthemarketequilibrium (PackandSaggi,2006). Most discussions of industrial policy invoke the examples of East Asian newly industrialising countries (NICs) such as Taiwan and Republic of Korea, which implemented industrial policy and secured historically unprecedented rates of growthofoutput,productivity,andpovertyreduction. 1

Thereareeconomistswhorecognisetheroleofindustrialpolicyinunderpinningthe successof latedevelopers suchastherepublicofkoreabutwhoremainextremely pessimistic about the prospects of successful industrial policy in Africa. The well6 known economist Dani Rodrik is one such commentator: I come down on the pessimisticside,duetowhatithinkarepoorprospectsforindustrialization Africa findsitselfinanenvironmentwhereitisfacingmuchstrongerheadwinds Having liberalized trade, African countries have to compete today with Asian and other exporters not only on world markets, but also in their domestic markets (Rodrik, 2014). Nonetheless, Rodrik bemoans anti6growth structural change in Africa (as wellaslatinamerica)inrecentyears thatis,thefactthatgrowthhasbeendriven morebyprimarycommoditysectors. Giventherisksinvolved,theevidencethatindustrialpolicyhasoftenfailedtomeet itsstatedaims,andtheweightofeconomictheorywarningagainstinterferingwith the signals emitted by flexible market prices, why should one try to design and implement industrial policy? The strongest response is that there is something uniqueaboutthemanufacturingsector.ifeconomicdevelopmentisamatterofan increasing proportion of the population shifting from low to higher productivity activities, then manufacturing generally involves higher productivity production thanmuchofagriculture.butthereismoretothisargumentthanthisassumption. Thoughmanyofthecurrentadvocatesofindustrialpolicydonotacknowledgethe earlier incarnations of their ideas, a powerful source of inspiration for industrial policycomesintheworkoftheeconomistnicholaskaldor.inhisfamousgrowth laws, he proposed that the rate of growth of manufacturing output is related, positively and causally, to the rate of growth of the overall economy; that productivity growth in manufacturing is related to the rate of growth of manufacturingoutput(namely,thatthereareeconomiesofscale);andthegrowthof manufacturingoutputisalsolinkedtotheincreaseofproductivityelsewhereinthe economy. There are other reasons to promote industrial policy. The prices of unprocessed primarycommodityexportsaretypicallybothlowerandmorevolatilethanthoseof 2

manufactured goods. Many African countries rely on natural resource exports, whosepricesareespeciallyvolatile.andasafricaneconomiesgrow,theyrunintoa fundamental balance of payments constraint: their economies develop a rising propensity andneed6toimport,buttheyoftendonotexportenoughtocoverthe costsofincreasingimports.industrialpolicycanhelptoreduceimportcoststhrough import substitution; and it can help generate foreign exchange earnings through manufacturedexports. What is far less clear is whether industrial policy promotes rapid growth in employment. This is an especially pressing concern in economies with a demographiccompositionskewedtowardstheveryyoung.manufacturingtendsnot to be the main direct driver of employment. But it does play a vital role in stimulating employment overall, through its indirect effects on the demand for labour (for example, through raising demand for labour in the production of agriculturalinputstomanufacturing)andthroughinducinglabourdemandthrough the multiplier effect. This channel involves the process of those employed in high productivitymanufacturingearningrelativelyhighwages,muchofwhichtheythen spend, increasing the demand for, and then production of, many other goods and servicesproducedlocally. Government intervention to stimulate manufacturing is often deemed necessary because these benefits are unlikely to be achieved if the economy is left to market forces. The advantages enjoyed by those economies already sustaining large manufacturing sectors are just too great to allow for a level playing field. Competitionisfierceandmarketsaretiltedinfavourofthosethatalreadyhavethe know6howtoproduceathighproductivity. Catching up, becoming a competitive industrial producer nation, involves a huge amount of learning learning by doing, learning by copying appropriate role models, and learning by governments through making policy. Industrial policy means, typically, creating an environment in which this kind of learning can take place.thus,itinvolvesformsofprotectionandsupportforindustrialproducers. 3

Allofthesearereasonswhythereisageneralcaseforindustrialpolicyandacasefor Africainparticular.Thatcaseissharpenedbythepersistenceofahighincidenceof extremepovertyinmuchofafrica,despitedecadesofapovertyreductionagenda internationally,whichhasemphasisedmarketliberalization,soundmacro6economic policy, privatisation, good governance and social sector investment. It is also sharpenedbythefearthatrecentrapidratesofgdpgrowthinafricaneconomies aresimplythelatestepisodeinalong6runhistoryofspellsofgrowththathavebeen drivenbyexternalfactors(namely,cheapinternationalborrowing,asurgeinforeign capital inflows, low debt and high commodity prices) rather than being driven by systematicandmorelastinginternalstructuralfactors. Thecaseforindustrialpolicyisalsosharpenedbytheglaringbalanceofpayments deficitsinmanycountries(e.g.,thedeficithaswidenedintherecentyearsofgrowth inethiopia)andbythethreatto policyspace andpoliticalindependencethatthis processposes.anditissharpenedbythechallengeofabsorbingintothelabourforce a growing number of young people in a demographic structure biased strongly towardsyouth.butmostafricancountriesremaindependentonasmallnumberof primary commodity exports, and manufacturing value added remains a pitifully smallshareofgdp. Itisfairlystraightforwardtorecognisethe caseforindustrialpolicy.itisfarmore difficult to define how to specifically design and implement an effective industrial policy.butthereareanumberofkeyprinciples. First, the evidence suggests that industrial policy works best when it is applied selectively: not as a blanket set of supports to all industrial sectors but targeted support to particular sectors and enterprises, selected on the basis of a number of criteria. Second, industrial policy is completely ineffective if there is no discipline on these firmsandsectors.thereneedstobewhataliceamsdencalleda reciprocalcontrol mechanism :ifafirmistobenefitfromprotectivemeasuresthenithastobeheldto 4

strictlyenforcedtargets(suchasforoutput,exportgrowthandemployment),witha crediblethreatthatthesupportswillberemovedifitfallsshortoftargets. Third,industrialpolicyshouldbedesignedwithaviewtomaximisingthechancesof stimulating backward1 and1 forward1 linkages. Backward linkages occur where one activity (say, commercial timber and forestry) makes viable and prompts the developmentofproductionofinputsusedinthatactivity(e.g.,sawmillmachinery). Forward linkages take place where one activity makes possible and provokes investmentinnewactivitiesthatuseoutputfromthatactivityasaninput(e.g.,paper manufactureorfurnituremakingor,furtherdownthelineandatahigherlevelof technology,manufactureofcapitalgoodsusedinrelatedindustries). Thus,theexample of the developmentofthenationalcementindustryinethiopia hasinsomewaysbeentheproductofadeterminedefforttoexploitthepossibilities ofabackwardlinkageeffectfromaconstructionsectorthathasboomedonthebasis ofcommercialinvestmentandtherapidexpansionofurbancondominiumhousing programmes. Similarly, the expansion of the floriculture sector has led to the expansionofdomesticcardboardpackagingproductioninethiopiaaswellastothe development of new and more efficient logistics, and to cold storage and freight terminalservicesatboleinternationalairport,whichthenbecomeavailabletoand makemoreeconomicallyviablethewiderexpansionofexport6orientedhorticulture. Although Albert Hirschman s original setting out of the linkage framework suggested that linkages were more or less unavoidable economic compulsions, the reality is that linkages do not typically come about automatically; they require intensepolicyattention. Thefourthprincipleisthatindustrialpolicymightworkdifferentlyacrossdifferent sectorspartlybecauseofthespecificstructureofthosesectors.policymakershaveto consider how technologically demanding a given set of activities in a sector is. Nowadaysitisalsoespeciallyimportanttodevelopanunderstandingoftheglobal structure of production, which is often dominated by a small number of massive corporations with preponderant power over the distribution of and scope for 5

productionofcomponentsofa globalvaluechain.howeasyitistoimplementa policy might also depend on whether a sector is composed of a large number of mediumsizedfamilyfirmsorasmallnumberoflargebusinesses. The fifth principle, which is very much related to this last point, is that industrial policyisinherentlypolitical.theinterestsofpolicymakersneedtobealignedwith thebureaucracyresponsibleforpolicyimplementation includingthemonitoringof targets,andthemanagementofsubsidies,protectivetariffs,supportforresearchand development,anddevelopmentfinance.inaddition,iftheseeffortsarealignedwith a coherent, unified set of interests among economic actors in the sector, industrial policyhasagreaterchanceofsucceeding. Industry actors might then be effective in developing an organised voice with which to discuss concerns with the government and bureaucratic agencies. And therewouldbelesschancethatpolicymakersorbureaucratswillbe captured by specific interests, or that policy design and implementation will be confounded by conflictinginterestsinthesector. Aninformativeexampleinthisregardisthecontrastbetweenthecashewprocessing industry and the sugar business in Mozambique. The Mozambican government founditdifficulttoresistheavyexternalpressure,fromtheworldbank,tounravel completely rather than to just reform an industrial policy meant to support the cashew processing factories that had not been effective for years. One reason for ineffectiveness was that the cashew sector comprised different groups i.e., processors, farmers and traders whose interests directly conflicted with one another. By contrast, there was more agreement among the groups in the sugar sectorinthiscountry,whothereforemanagedtoworkcloselywithandencourage thedevelopmentofaprotectivepolicybythegovernment. The sixth principle is that industrial policy is about nurturing learning: learning to produce, to compete internationally, to organise production in efficient firms, to acquireandadapttechnologies,andtodevelopproductivity6enhancinginstitutions andsupportivegovernance.thisprocessinvolvesarangeofactivities pragmatic 6

assessment of the merits of alternative experiences in other countries (e.g., with industrialzonesorinfrastructureprovisionortradepolicy);studytoursandtheuse ofresearchonotherrelevantpolicyexperiences;acquiringunderstandingofspecific global markets and the scope for adding value through branding techniques; and, perhapsaboveall,encouragingresearchanddevelopmentwithinlargefirmsandat thegovernmentlevelasapublicgood. SupportingR&Disoneofthecorepoliciesincountrieswithverydifferentkindsof industrialpolicysuchastherepublicofkorea,brazilandfinland.furthermore,itis not adequate to have dedicated R&D organizations or to subsidise R&D efforts in specific sectors. Industrial policy requires some form of long6term development finance. Whatever the institutional solution that a particular country finds with regardtothischallenge,itisimportantthatdevelopmentbankshirepeoplewhoare not just trained in finance but are also experts in the specific sectors that will be supportedbydevelopmentfinance. Fundamentally, it is impossible effectively to make good selective choices in industrialpolicy,create reciprocal6control discipliningmechanisms,anddecisively enforcesuchchoicesifthestatecannotimposeitspolicyonapoliticallyfragmented, dividedorundulypowerfulsetofsectoralinterestgroups. Thisfactorisprobablymorecriticalthananotherimportant,butextremelydifficult, challenge: not only how to do industrial policy but how1 much? The answer to this question divides economists. One of the neatest divisions is captured by a debate between those who like the former Chief Economist of the World Bank and advocate of a new structuralist development economics, Justin Lin argue for a facilitative state that uses industrial policy to follow and encourage comparative advantage and those who, like Ha6Joon Chang, argue that the state needs to take bolderstepstochallengeordefycomparativeadvantage. Essentially, this choice is related to an underlying difference on core economic principlesandonakindofriskprofile.challengingcomparativeadvantagewitha more Kaldorian strategy is certainly a higher risk option but perhaps it would 7

have greater rewards if successful than a more modest, cautious, comparative advantageapproachthatfollowsa Ricardian strategy.neitheroptioniseasy.but ifgovernmentsaretoadoptamorekaldorianstrategy,theonusisonthemtopay particularattentiontotheprincipleslistedabove:tothepoliticsofindustrialpolicy, toselectivity,tolearning,andtothedesignofdiscipliningmeasuresaswellasforms ofactivesupport. Finally, industrial policy in low6income countries is implemented in the context of extreme balance of payments constraints and substantial challenges posed by technology,infrastructureandalearningandproductivitygap.butthesechallenges do not constitute a reason to avoid industrial policy. As Hirschman wrote, developmentisaboutwhatacountrydoes,andwhatitbecomesasaresultofwhatit does ratherthanaboutwhatitis(namely,its endowments ). While industrial policy develops and takes time to produce results, policy has to promoterisingproductivityin,andarapidrateofgrowthofexportearningsfrom, agriculture.thischallengeposesafinalquestion:canindustrialpolicyprinciplesbe appliedtoagriculturalpolicy.theanswerisyes.thoughthegainsmight nottake quite the same form, agriculture is crucial to economic development and catching up. Generating rapid improvements in agricultural productivity and export earnings requires versions of the same techniques used in industrial policy. These include huge support for R&D (a very important example, or possible role model, is EmbrapainBrazil,thestateagriculturalR&Dorganization),targetedinfrastructure provision,andselectivesupportforthebestproducers(conditionalon,forexample, theircontributiontoexportsand/oremployment). References Pack, Howard and Kamal Saggi, 2006. The case for industrial policy: a critical survey. WorldBankPolicyResearchWorkingPaper3839,TheWorldBank. 8

Rodrik, Dani, 2014. An African Growth Miracle? CEPR Discussion Paper No. DP10005,CentreforEconomicPolicyResearch. 9