UNIVERSITÀ DEGLI STUDI DI PADOVA. Dipartimento di Scienze Economiche ed Aziendali Marco Fanno

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "UNIVERSITÀ DEGLI STUDI DI PADOVA. Dipartimento di Scienze Economiche ed Aziendali Marco Fanno"

Transcription

1 UNIVERSITÀ DEGLI STUDI DI PADOVA Dipartimento di Scienze Economiche ed Aziendali Marco Fanno THE ROLE OF PATENTS IN INFORMATION AND COMMUNICATION TECHNOLOGIES (ICTS). A SURVEY OF THE LITERATURE. STEFANO COMINO University of Udine FABIO M. MANENTI University of Padova NIKOLAUS THUMM European Commission JRC - Seville June 2017 MARCO FANNO WORKING PAPER N.212

2 The Role of Patents in Information and Communication Technologies (ICTs). A survey of the Literature. 1 Stefano Comino 2 Dept. of Economics and Statistics Università di Udine Fabio M. Manenti Dept. of Economics and Management Università di Padova Nikolaus Thumm Joint Research Centre European Commission Seville June 2017 Abstract During the last decades, the number of ICT related patents has increased considerably. In association with a great fragmentation in IP rights, the increasing number of patents has generated a series of potentially problematic consequences. Patent thickets, royalty stacking, the emergence of patent assertion entities, increased patent litigation in particular around standard essential patents and the difficulties in the definition of fair, reasonable and non-discriminatory (FRAND) licensing terms are among the most debated issues in the literature that we review in this paper. We devote a specific section of our survey to patents involving software products, where the above problems are amplified by the high level of abstraction of computer algorithms. In our analysis we mix theoretical and empirical arguments with a more policy-oriented reasoning. This allows us to better position the different issues in the relevant political and economic context. 1. Introduction The dynamics of the knowledge economy in today s globalized markets and the increasing complexity of products have radically modified firms intellectual property (IP) strategies and have led to an enormous growth in the number of patent applications. The proliferation of patents and their increasing fragmentation have produced a series of consequences patent thickets, royalty stacking, augmented litigation, difficulties in the definition of licensing terms for patents related to standardized technologies... that are seen as potentially problematic. In this paper, we survey the economic literature on the role of patents in information and communication technologies (ICTs) 1 This work is the continuation of a collaboration that took place within the EU research project EURIPIDIS European Innovation Policies for the Digital Shift (see Comino and Manenti, 2015). We thank Knut Blind for comments on an earlier version of this survey. 2 Corresponding author. Address for correspondence: Department of Economics and Statistics, via Tomadini 30/A, Udine (Italy), stefano.comino@uniud.it. 1

3 where much of the surge in patenting has taken place and where these changes in the IP landscape are most striking. ICTs intended as the set of technologies aimed at processing, storing and transmitting information (including telecommunication equipment, consumer electronics, computers and software products) are among the most dynamic and innovative segments of modern economies. They now permeate all aspects of our everyday life, impacting virtually all the sectors of the economy. ICTs are changing the way firms do business and are transforming the delivery of public services. Telecommunication networks are shaping the way social interactions take place, and the convergence of digital technologies is making it possible the so-called Internet of things, i.e. the increased connectedness of individuals and things on an unprecedented scale. In this extremely dynamic environment, it is crucial to understand how IP can be effectively used to stimulate and protect innovations. ICTs are highly heterogeneous and differ in nature and characteristics; however, they share some features which are relevant when evaluating the role of patents. They are complex technologies combining several different technological components. Innovation in ICTs is a highly cumulative process, with follow-on inventions often representing improvements or re-combinations of previous products or technologies. As we will discuss in this survey, these characteristics lead to fragmentation of IP rights and to the emergence of the so-called patent thickets. In this scenario, the role of patents in stimulating innovation and technology transfer is extremely controversial. Several actors and institutions such as patent pools, standard setting organizations and patent intermediaries - have developed to cope with the increased technological complexity and to allow market players to hack their way through the patent thicket (Shapiro, 2001). However, as we document in detail, these institutions have generated a series of additional concerns. They typically require close collaboration among rival firms and for this reason they are often scrutinized by antitrust authorities. On top of this, as witnessed by the debate on FRAND licensing, members of pools and standard setting organizations may have divergent interests and goals thus making it difficult for them to reach a consensual agreement on licensing schemes. The goal of intermediaries is to increase the efficiency of the market for patent related transactions. Among the various types of intermediaries, patent assertion entities (PAEs) have raised considerable public attention. They are alleged to be one of the major responsible for the surge in patent lawsuits; born as an high-tech phenomenon, PAEs are now broadening their scope of action towards other industrial sectors such as biotech and pharmaceuticals. A noticeable share in the increase in patenting can be ascribed to the software industry. Estimates reveal that about one third of the patents granted by the EPO and the USPTO are related to software products. Patents protecting software technologies are very controversial. As a matter of fact, the high degree of abstraction of software algorithms makes it difficult to assess their patentability and this raises concerns about the quality of the granted rights. A large share of the lawsuits in the recent smartphone war involved patents protecting software related technologies, a fact that is considered by many as a confirmation of the concerns regarding the low quality of software patents. Differences with the legal scope of patents for software technologies in the various jurisdictions and the heterogeneity in the examination rules at different patent offices have further contributed to the uncertainty in the field. The picture is made even more compelling due to the increasingly significant role of open source software. Based on the openness of the source code, this innovative way of creating and distributing computer programs needs to find its way to coexist with patented software. 2

4 This paper is organized as follows: in Section 2 we document the surge in patents and their changing role in ICTs, while Section 3 surveys the main theoretical contributions on the role of patenting in industries where innovation proceeds cumulatively. Section 4 presents the main problems associated with IP fragmentation and Sections 5 and 6 focus on patent pools and standard setting organizations, the traditional institutions aimed at copying with fragmentation. Section 7 discusses the literature on the market for ideas, focusing, in particular, on the role of intermediaries and PAEs. We devote Section 8 to software patents. Finally, Section 9 concludes. 2. The surge in ICT patenting Patent applications increased steadily during the last decades. For the year 2014, WIPO (2016) estimates that the number of applications filed world-wide amounted to more than 2.4 million, a figure which is approximately three times that estimated in the 80s. About one third of these applications were filed within the ICT-related sectors. Similarly OECD (2014), looking at patents filed under the Patent Cooperation Treaty (PCT), finds that between 2009 and 2011 ICT patents were over 38% of the total. A noteworthy trend is the increase in software patenting, as we document in Section 8. The surge in the number of patents seems to be at odds with what was found by Graham et al. (2010) in a survey on 1,332 US high-tech start-ups active in biotech, medical devices, software and IT hardware (semiconductors, communications and computer hardware). According to their evidence, for technology entrepreneurs the patent system seems neither working particularly poorly nor well for their companies and industries. Interestingly, software companies consider patents as the least important mechanism to appropriate the returns of their R&D efforts. 3 The finding that innovators very often do not perceive patents as an effective instrument to protect their innovation is wellknown in the literature since the widely cited study by Cohen et al. (2000). These contrasting figures, surge in patenting and little effectiveness of patents as an appropriation mechanism, gave rise to what has been dubbed as the patent paradox. This paradox can be explained by considering the changing role that patents have in modern economies and in ICTs in particular. Hoeren et al. (2015) offer an interesting historical analysis of the evolution of IP protection in semiconductors. They show that since the early stages of the industry, manufacturers relied heavily on patents; however, firms used them essentially as an effective means of sharing technologies and rarely enforced them. Today, things have changed. In semiconductors, as well as in other industrial sectors with complex technologies, patents are often used as bargaining chips in order to improve the outcomes of licensing/cross-licensing negotiations (Hall and Ziedonis, 2001). The literature on strategic patenting is relatively abundant. On the hand, large patent portfolios have been considered as an important defensive safeguard against the possibility of rival firms taking legal actions for patent infringement (Ziedonis, 2004). On the other hand, patents can be used aggressively against competitors. This use of patents has become very relevant and for this reason it has attracted the attention of researchers. Walsh et al. (2016) and Torrisi et al. (2016) represent two of the most recent studies conducted on this issue. Walsh et al. (2016) use a random sample of 9,060 US triadic patents observed in the period and investigate the 3 Patents are considered to be less effective than secrecy, first mover advantage, complementary assets, copyright and trademarks. 3

5 importance of preemption, that is, the use of patents to block competitors or to prevent them from inventing around. The authors find that compared to other technological areas, patents protecting computer and semiconductor technologies show high rates of preemptive use. Interestingly, they also find that the likelihood of using patents preemptively is positively associated with the strength of patent protection. A confirmation of the importance of strategic motives for patenting in ICTs is in Torrisi et al. (2016). They use survey data on inventors from 23 countries (European countries, Israel, the United States and Japan) filing applications at the EPO between 2003 and The authors show that a substantial share of patents is not being used by firms internally or for market transactions and they interpret this evidence as a support to the importance of strategic patenting. They also find significant differences across industrial sectors, with patents that are more likely to be employed strategically in complex technologies than in other areas. One of the sectors where patenting has increased the most during the recent years is software. Bessen and Hunt (2007) argue that the rise in software patents can only partially be explained with an increase in innovation and in research and development, while it is mainly related to strategic motives. They support this view by looking at the distribution by industry of software patents granted by the USPTO. It emerges that three out of four software patents do not belong to software publishers but to firms operating in some manufacturing industries (specifically, 28% in electronics and 24% in machinery); software publishers, in principle the companies mostly involved in the development of software programs, account for only 5% of the overall number of patents. By contrast, the share of programmers and engineers, i.e. those involved in the writing of software code, is much larger in software publishers and in non-manufacturing sectors. Only 11% of the overall programmers and 32% of the total number of programmers and engineers are employed in the manufacturing sector. These figures suggest that there is little correspondence between the R&D activity aimed at developing new software and patent ownership. At the same time, companies in manufacturing industries have greater propensity to amass large patent portfolios despite employing a small fraction of programmers. This evidence, according to Bessen and Hunt (2007), represents a clear signal of strategic patenting in software. On top of strategic uses, the empirical literature has shown that patents play also an important signaling role for start-ups and SMEs. A series of studies focus on ICTs and show that possessing a large stock of patents increases the chances of companies of being financed by venture capitalists (Cockburn and MacGarvie, 2009 and 2011) as well as it affects the amount the investment received (Mann and Sager, 2007). 3. Patents and cumulative innovation In the theoretical literature, innovation is often described as a discrete event taking place once and for all, with no links to any past or future invention. Although useful in order to focus on the tradeoff between incentives to innovate and deadweight loss and to clarify the basic role of patents, the isolated innovation approach does not capture several critical features characterizing the inventive process in high-tech industries. The cumulativeness and complexity of innovation in ICTs make the role of patents less clear-cut provided that a strengthening of the protection they guarantee may have heterogeneous effects on the different generations of innovators. More generally, in order to understand the role of patents in ICT sectors one needs to consider additional effects, beyond the traditional trade-off highlighted in the isolated innovation framework. 4

6 With a cumulative innovation process, early inventions pave the way for follow-on innovators and technology implementers. The social value of early innovations is not only related to the utility generated from their use but also to the positive externality they contribute to future applications/developments see Scotchmer, 2004 for a thorough discussion on the cumulative nature of the innovation process. At the same time, patent protection, while increasing the R&D incentives of early innovators, may discourage follow-on inventors and technology implementers from investing. By anticipating the licensing fees due to the owners of the relevant patents, or the cost of being involved in litigation, they may choose suboptimal levels of investment or may not invest at all. This is what is known in the literature as the hold-up problem in technology innovation (Lemley and Shapiro, 2007). 4 Another potential inefficiency in the context of cumulative innovation is related to the so-called reverse hold-up, often referred to as hold-out problem. In this case, it is the follow-on inventor/implementer who, infringing on a patent, opportunistically refuses to enter into a licensing agreement with the inventor. While the empirical literature has highlighted instances where the hold-out emerges (Pentheroudakis and Baron, 2017), the theoretical contributions have mainly neglected this issue. With cumulative innovation, also the effect of imitation on R&D incentives should be reconsidered. Bessen and Maskin (2009) observe that imitation affects firm s profitability in two ways. In the shortrun, imitators compete with the innovator, thus reducing the profits of this latter. However, in the longer run, the innovator may, in turn, imitate future inventions developed by competitors, therefore providing consumers with more innovative and technologically advanced products. This second, long-run, effect increases the incentives to innovate. Bessen and Maskin (2009) believe that in highly dynamic industries such as software, personal computers and semiconductors, the long-run effect dominates the short-run one and innovation may be fostered by the possibility of imitation. Therefore, in these industries innovation would flourish in the presence of lower levels of patent protection allowing some degree of imitation. The impact of patent rights on the overall innovation incentives and on the diffusion of the protected technologies is intimately related to the efficiency of negotiations among different generations of inventors/implementers. In one of the most influential contributions in this field, Green and Scotchmer (1995) show that the absence of failures in the bargaining over the licensing terms restores efficient incentives for the whole sequence of innovators. However, as we detail in the following sections, the literature has highlighted different reasons why negotiations may fail. Asymmetric information among contracting parties, the fragmentation of IP rights typical of ICT industries and the often alleged low quality of granted patents severely hamper the efficiency of licensing negotiations. As regards the effects of low quality patents the contribution of Farrell and Shapiro (2008) deserves to be mentioned. They show that low-quality patents (what the authors call weak patents) may generate two forms of inefficiencies. On the one hand, there is a free-riding effect reducing the incentives to go to Court looking for invalidation; all follow-on innovators benefit from patent invalidation, but the cost of filing a lawsuit is borne only by the plaintiff. On the other hand, patents, 4 It is interesting to notice that, in the theoretical literature, the terms follow-on inventors and implementers are often used interchangeably and the distiction between these two figures is rather blurred. 5

7 even the low quality ones, allow patent holders to set fees strategically in the attempt to reduce competition among implementers, thus maximizing licensing revenues. While the theoretical literature on the effects of patents on cumulative innovation is quite abundant, the empirical evidence is relatively scant. This is not surprising given the difficulties both in measuring cumulativeness and in identifying the causal effect of patents on innovation. Galasso and Schankerman (2015) represent a notable exception. They study the impact on follow-on research of the removal of patent rights by court invalidation in the US. The authors measure followon innovation using later citations and solve the identification problem thanks to the fact that the US Court of Appeal for the Federal Circuit institutionally allocates judges to patent cases randomly; this allows the authors to control for the potential endogeneity of patent invalidation. According to their estimates, Galasso and Schankerman (2015) find that patents hinder follow-on innovation in computers, electronics, and medical instruments; by contrast no effects are found in drugs, chemicals, and mechanical technologies. Interestingly, they provide evidence of invalidation stimulating subsequent innovation only in relation to patents owned by large companies. 4. Fragmentation of patent rights In ICT industrial sectors, a series of factors the cumulativeness of the innovation process, the complexity of technologies, and the increasing patenting volumes has naturally led to a high degree of fragmentation of patent rights and to the emergence of the so-called patent thickets. Often the various components essential for the functioning of a technological system are controlled by a large and dispersed number of operators; this fragmentation in property rights potentially constraints the ability to operate and forces companies to secure the necessary licenses in order to hack their way through the patent thicket (Shapiro, 2001). The prevalence of fragmentation/thickets in ICT-related sectors is confirmed in Hall et al., (2013) and Graevenitz et al. (2013). The authors identify thickets by counting triples i.e. groups of three firms in which each of them is in a mutually blocking relationship with the other two due to the patents they own. Using information on patent applications filed at the EPO, Hall et al., (2013) find a high number of thickets in all areas belonging to Electrical Engineering, especially in Telecommunications, Audiovisual Technology, and Computer Technology. Interestingly, they also find that some large ICT companies are responsible for a relevant share of thickets in other technological fields (e.g. Instruments). For easiness of exposition, in what follows, we group the main contributions in the literature regarding the consequences of fragmentation and patent thickets into three areas. Fragmentation and royalty stacking/anticommons The economic literature suggests that patent thickets may lead to multiple marginalizations and royalty stacking (Shapiro, 2001); hence, fragmentation potentially amplifies the distortions associated with upstream monopolists. In an often cited theoretical study on biomedical research, Heller and Eisenberg (1998) warn against what they call the tragedy of the anti-commons. With highly dispersed patent rights reading on a single technology, implementers are forced to negotiate a large number of licensing agreements and this fact may reduce their incentives to use the technology altogether. Lichtman (2006) holds a quite different view. A high degree of fragmentation implies that each patent grants control over a limited part of the technology. This fact reduces the bargaining power of patent holders who, in turn, negotiate licensing agreements less and less 6

8 aggressively. The overall effect of fragmentation, according to Lichtman, is to facilitate licensing negotiations, thus favoring access to the technology. Galasso and Schankerman (2010) present a theoretical model incorporating the views both of Heller and Eisenberg as well as that of Lichtman. As fragmentation rises two contrasting effects emerge. On the one hand, the negotiation process becomes more complex provided that the number of agreements to be signed gets larger. On the other hand, however, since the value of each patent reduces with fragmentation, negotiations about each licensing agreement speed up. Whether fragmentation discourages (royalty stacking/anticommons view) or favors (Lichtman s view) technology implementation depends on which effect dominates. By using data on patent disputes in U.S. district courts, Galasso and Schankerman (2010) test their model by estimating how fragmentation affects the length of licensing negotiations. The authors find weak evidence that fragmentation accelerates the negotiation process; this moderately supports Lichtman s argument. Patent pendency and patent quality The surge in patenting and the associated fragmentation of IP rights have increased the backlog of patent offices. An undesirable consequence of large backlogs is that they increase the pendency periods, i.e. the time between the filing of a patent application and the granting decision by the patent office. Pendency is costly for applicants as it delays the time from which they can benefit from their innovations being fully protected; long pendency rates are costly for non-applicants too, as they increase uncertainty over the technology they can freely use (IPO, 2013). 5 Large patenting volumes may also affect the quality of patents intended as the ability of a patent to meet the statutory patentability requirements, to leave little doubt as to its breadth, and to disclose information that enables a person skilled in the art to implement the protected invention (EPO, 2012a). Under the pressure of ever increasing backlogs, examiners necessarily devote less and less time in screening applications. This issue seems to be particularly severe in the U.S.; in an influential book, Jaffe and Lerner (2004) argue that the USPTO has been issuing a significant number of low quality patents. 6 de Rassenfosse et al. (2016) evaluate the quality of patents by comparing the decisions of different PTOs regarding the protection of the same innovation. They estimate that about 2-6% of granted patents are of dubious validity, i.e. they appear to be inconsistent with the Office s own standards and, therefore, potentially invalid. 7 Interestingly, the authors find that the 5 It deserves to be noticed that according to industry experts pendency may have the positive effect of providing patent applicants with strategic options to explore the market before the final scope of protection is fixed. This is particularly important in highly competitive fields like ICT. 6 The issue of patent quality appears to be less relevant as regards EPO (Wild and Clover, 2015). No patent office grants patents of perfect quality as EPO opposition figures illustrate. EPO (2015) estimates that in 2014 some 4.5% of European patents were attacked by an opposition with the EPO board of appeal. Some 31% of these opposition cases led to the revocation of the patent and in another 38% of these cases the patent had to be limited in scope. 7 More specifically, de Rassenfosse et al. (2016) distinguish two conceptually distinct reasons why low quality patents may be granted: i) Patent offices systematically apply too lenient standards for patentability; ii) the examination process is superficial so that undeserved (i.e. patents inconsistent with the patent offices' own standards) and potentially invalid patents are granted. In both cases, patent protection is not worth to be granted. In their empirical analysis, based on a sample of more than 400 thousand applications filed at different patent offices, the authors find that on top of the 2-6% patents of dubious validity, another 2-15% is estimated to be of low quality in the sense that they would not have been granted were the (stricter) standards of some other patent offices being applied. 7

9 share of patents of dubious validity is higher in frontier industries such as software and biotechnology. Fragmentation and innovation incentives From a theoretical perspective, the consequences of patent fragmentation on the incentives to innovate are not easy to predict, as they likely depend on firm and market characteristics. On the one hand, firms that rely heavily on the technology developed by others mainly new entrants or SMEs may have reduced incentives to invest in R&D as they fear to be held-up by competitors. In addition, companies may be forced to devote substantial parts of their budgets in the attempt to build large patent portfolios aimed at improving their bargaining position when negotiating crosslicensing agreements. On the other hand, fragmentation may encourage innovation of technology leaders mainly large incumbents and companies holding sizeable patent portfolios who can leverage the mass of patents they possess. 8 The empirical literature on patent fragmentation is relatively scarce mainly due to the lack of suitable data. Nevertheless, the available contributions confirm that the consequences of thickets are differentiated and depend on company characteristics and market specificities. Graevenitz et al. (2013) focus on the patenting behaviour of 2,074 firms filing applications at the EPO between 1978 and Their analysis confirms that for complex technologies like telecommunications, large and small firms react to patent fragmentation differently; while firms holding large portfolios patent more intensively as thicket density increases, holders of fewer patents reduce their applications in response to larger and denser thickets. Hall et al. (2013) look at how thickets influence firms entry, defined as the decision to patent for the first time in a given technology area. They employ a sample of about 29 thousand UK SMEs observed over the period Using duration regression analysis, they find that the propensity to patent for the first time in a given technology area is negatively affected by thickets density; again, this evidence confirms that small firms are the ones that are eventually most harmed by thickets. Cockburn et al. (2010) find that fragmentation has a differentiated impact on companies depending on whether they need to in-license the technology they use. The authors measure firms innovative activity in terms of the share of sales from new products. They find a negative relationship between fragmentation and their proxy for innovation in the case of firms needing to license the technology from rivals. By contrast, companies that do not in-license increase their share of sales from new products the greater the fragmentation. 5. Patent pools Historically, the two ways that market participants have employed to cope with IP fragmentation are patent pools and standard setting organisations (SSOs). Patent pools can be defined as an agreement between two or more patent owners to license one or more of their patents to one another or to third parties (WIPO, 2014). Pools represent a one-stop-shop through which an implementer can access the package of patents belonging to several owners and reading on the relevant technology. Therefore, they significantly reduce the transaction costs associated with 8 In a 2012 workshop on patents thickets, experts (practitioners, policy makers and academics) agreed that patent thickets are a consequence of technological complexity and high competition and as such are more likely to harm SMEs and individual inventors; these are less able to cope with the cost of complexity, namely the costs associated with: the uncertainty over freedom to operate, the lack of transparency, the search of relevant prior art and legal actions (EPO, 2012b). 8

10 thickets and are seen as a potential solution to inefficiencies resulting from fragmented and overlapping patents. Patent pools require close collaboration among member firms. As these companies are often rivals in the product market, much of the economic analysis has looked at pools from a competition policy perspective; as a matter of fact, an increasing number of antitrust cases deal with patent pooling arrangements (Gilbert, 2004). In this respect, two interrelated issues are relevant in order to evaluate the effects of patent pools. The first one, relates to the degree of substitutability or complementarity of patents forming the pool; the second one regards the possibility of independent licensing. A well-established result in the theoretical literature is that patent pools are anti-competitive when they include patents that are perfect substitutes while they increase market efficiency in the case of perfect complements (Shapiro, 2001; Lerner and Tirole, 2004). When patents are perfect substitutes, the pool eliminates competition on royalties among holders of patents addressing exactly the same functionalities; therefore, in this case, the members of the pool benefit from reduced competition to the detriment of market efficiency, as in a standard cartel. By contrast, when technologies are perfect complements, pools are pro-competitive as members internalize that larger royalties reduce the demand for complementary patents and, consequently, they are induced to lower licensing fees. In other words, with perfect complements, patent pools mitigate royalty stacking. Lerner and Tirole (2008) highlight that these arguments apply neatly but only in the extreme cases of perfect substitutes/complements. In the intermediate cases of imperfect complementarity or substitutability of patents, the consequences of pools are more nuanced. The authors show that the desirability of patent pools depends on a series of conditions such as the ability of prospective licensors to invent around, their capacity to invalidate patents or the possibility of pool members to grant individual licenses. The role of individual licensing on pools efficiency has been investigated more in detail in Lerner and Tirole (2004). The two authors show when the pool is aimed at increasing royalties (as in the case of substitutes patents) independent licensing restores competition among pool members and therefore it is welfare enhancing; on the opposite, with complementary patents, competition in royalties does not produce any effect. Lerner and Tirole s arguments support the approach followed by competition authorities that often impose independent licensing to pool members; the authors, in fact, suggest that independent licensing reduces profitability of bad pools, i.e. pools aimed at increasing royalties. Another issue that has been extensively studied in the literature regards the effects of the so-called grant-back clauses. A grant-back clause requires pool members to disclose and transfer all improvements made in the licensed technology for free or at a low price. Such a requirement generates a trade-off between lower incentives to innovate and lower risk of hold-up. With grant back clauses, firms may be discouraged from innovating as they anticipate lower returns from the licensing of future patents. However, grant-back clauses protect from members opportunism; for example, they prevent companies from hiding essential innovations in an attempt to hold-up other members once the pool has formed (Lerner and Tirole, 2008). The empirical evidence on the effects of patent pools on firms innovative activities in ICTs is mixed. Joshi and Nerkar (2011) analyze data on innovation in the global optical disc industry and find that patent pools have significantly decreased both the quantity and the quality of patents obtained by 9

11 pool members. Based on this evidence, the authors suggest that pools seem actually to inhibit, rather than stimulate, innovation. Vakili (2012) investigates the impact of the MPEG-2 pool focusing on the innovation rate of outsider firms that are technologically proximate to the pool. Also this study finds a negative effect of the pool, with outsider firms innovating less after the pool formation. However, by looking at the underlying mechanisms driving this result, Vakili (2012) shows that the observed reduction in innovation rates is mainly due to a shift in firms strategy: investments in technological exploration seems to have been replaced by greater efforts in implementing the MPEG-2 technology in their own products. These negative effects of pools on innovation incentives are questioned by Baron and Pohlmann (2015). According to the two authors, in order to better understand the consequences for innovation one should also take into account the dynamics of patenting before the actual formation of the pool. More specifically, Baron and Pohlmann (2015) collect information on 50 patent pools in ICT industries; some of these pools were announced but then failed to take-off while others were also actually implemented. The authors find a significant increase in patenting just after the announcement of the pool; the effect is stronger for pools that were not only announced but that, later on, were also actually formed. Prospective members of the pool contributed the most to the increase in patenting in this pre-formation period. Based on these findings, the authors suggest that the decline in innovation activities found in previous articles on patent pools should be interpreted cautiously, as one should also look at the dynamics just before the advent of the pool. 6. Standard setting organizations and FRAND licensing Together with pools, Standard Setting Organizations (SSOs) are the other traditional institutional arrangement useful to cope with the inefficiencies related to fragmentation. Standards are ubiquitous in ICT industries due to the strong need for interoperability. Typically, SSOs are formed by industry stakeholders who endorse a particular technology and promote its adoption among market participants (Simcoe, 2011). Standards aim at facilitating the deployment of new technologies on the largest possible scale and create a level playing field for competition in related product markets. Standardized technologies include a large number of patented inventions; the prospect of licensing patents that are essential to standards the so-called standard-essential patents (SEPs) on an industry-wide scale is a major incentive for companies to invest in standardization activities. Most SSOs have defined intellectual property rights policies whereby members commit to licensing their SEPs on fair, reasonable and non-discriminatory (FRAND) terms (Meniere, 2015). The debate on FRAND licensing As discussed in Meniere (2015), until the 1990s, when SSOs started adopting FRAND policies, licensing negotiations took place among few companies with quite aligned interests, all involved both in the development and in the implementation of the standard. These vertically integrated companies typically ended-up cross-licensing their SEPs, thus paying little royalties to each other. By contrast, today the rapid evolution of information and communication technologies, coupled with the need for wider and deeper interconnectivity, has led to a variety of SEP owners and implementers with different business models and to a greater diversity of licensing practices. As a result, it has become more difficult to identify a consensual interpretation of FRAND licensing principles. It is often argued that FRAND commitments are too loose to effectively prevent SEP owners from unduly leveraging market power once the standard is implemented ( hold-up 10

12 argument). Others argue that FRAND commitments enable technology implementers to deliberately avoid seeking licenses for SEPs ( hold-out argument). Moreover, the fragmentation of SEP ownership might lead to an excessively high royalty stack ( royalty stacking argument) (Baron et al., 2016a). The theoretical literature on FRAND licensing has mainly focused on the hold-up problem and on the exact meaning of reasonable royalty rates. The basic argument suggesting the risk of hold-up is quite simple and rests on the idea that, once a standard is defined, the industry is locked-in and SEP owners gain monopolistic positions; as a matter of fact, before the standard is defined several technologies compete to be included in the standard while, once the standard has been developed and adopted, implementers are forced to use the, by then essential, technologies. The distinction between the ex-ante and the ex-post values of the technologies is at the heart of Swanson and Baumol s (2005) influential paper. The two authors suggest that a SEP should be remunerated according to its incremental value, that is the valuation that would emerge in an auction or other forms of bargaining among substitute technologies prior (ex-ante) to the definition of the standard. Though theoretically elegant, this proposal faces some practical problems; first of all, the royalty rates are actually set ex-post, when the standard is at the commercialization stage. If this is the case, it might be difficult to have a full understanding of the competing technologies that were available at the time of the definition of the standard. For this reason an SSO s best practice would be to keep track of the ex-ante feasible technologies in order to inform subsequent negotiators and arbitrators of the technical alternatives (Lemley and Shapiro, 2013). Another difficulty in implementing the incremental value criterion rests on the fact that typical licensing negotiations involve several SEPs and this makes the determination of the value of each patent an extremely complicated matter (Gupta, 2013). An even more serious shortcoming of the incremental value criterion is highlighted in Layne-Farrar and Llobet (2014); when, ex-ante, the difference between competing technologies is one-dimensional (e.g. they are identical but differ only in production costs), the incremental value can be determined rather easily. However, as technologies are of interest of many users with different needs and preferences, there is not a unique incremental value which, instead, is userspecific. One issue that has attracted the attention of researchers regards the practical implementation of FRAND licensing. Typically, FRAND provisions do not impose specific obligations for the determination of SEPs licensing terms; rather, they define a general framework and leave the identification of the exact conditions to negotiations between patent holders and implementers. If, on the one side, this flexibility allows parties to tailor the agreements to their specificities, on the other side it comes at the cost of a lack of transparency and of a larger degree of uncertainty (Meniere, 2015). Practitioners and industry experts argue in favor of this flexibility, but they also recognize that some limitations might help in reducing uncertainty and the associated transaction costs. Meniere (2015) lists a set of possible interventions, including the disclosure of information on SEP licensing conditions; knowing the terms of previous agreements may help current negotiators in defining a benchmark for the determination of reasonable rates. Moving from the observation that FRAND commitments are ambiguous, Lerner and Tirole (2015) build a theoretical framework that highlights the main trade-offs arising in the determination of the licensing terms of standard essential patents. They suggest to impose patent holders a commitment to a maximum royalty before the definition of the standard. In a manner which is reminiscent of 11

13 Swanson and Baumol (2005) arguments, ex-ante competition in royalty caps among technologies willing to be included in the standard would be a way to restore efficiency. In principle, the commitment to royalty caps proposed by Lerner and Tirole (2015) would made FRAND provisions redundant; nonetheless, the inability of SSOs to identify all the relevant technologies limits the efficacy of royalty caps and calls for the adoption of FRAND commitments anyway. In the view of the authors, therefore, royalty caps and FRAND commitments would complement each other. A different issue that has attracted the attention of the economic literature on SSOs regards the quality of SEPs; the discussion has been fuelled by the recent smartphone war discussed later in the survey which is seen by many as caused by the presence of essential patents of low quality. Regibeau et al. (2016) suggest to impose a significant declaration fee for SEPs and regular essentiality tests of a random sample of SEPs. Testing essentiality of SEPs would raise their quality and could considerably contribute to reduce transaction costs. It is not clear, however, who should carry out these tests, what the costs would be and who would bear them. Analyzing the case of ETSI, the European Telecommunications standards Institute, Pohlmann and Blind (2016) suggest that SEPs tests might be carried out by the European Patent Office. Rysman and Simcoe (2008) provide different evidence on the quality of SEPs. They use information collected from the publicly available IPR disclosure archives of four major SSOs (ANSI, IEEE, IETF and the ITU) between 1971 and 2006, and find that, prior to disclosure, patents reading on standards receive roughly double the citation rate of an average patent. They interpret this finding as evidence of a high quality of SEPs, with SSOs performing well in selecting technologies with higher inherent merit. The role of courts in FRAND licensing A related matter of contention regards the role of courts in case licensing negotiations fail. In the US, courts play an active role in the determination of the licensing terms; reasonable royalties are determined on the basis of a hypothetical negotiation that would have taken place between the parties before the infringement. As stressed in Pentheroudakis and Baron (2017), US courts are methodologically sophisticated, 9 even though their approach based on a hypothetical negotiation appears to be quite difficult to be implemented in practice. European courts are, instead, more focused on the conduct of parties during negotiations and they specifically assess whether patent holders have complied with the obligations imposed by FRAND commitments. Some differences between the two sides of the Atlantic emerge also in relation to the imposition of injunctions. Traditionally, US courts have been reluctant to grant injunctive reliefs to SEP owners committed to FRAND licensing. In contrast, European courts tended to be more prone to concede injunctions; things have changed since the 2015 decision of the Court of Justice of the European Union in Huawei vs ZTE (Baron et al., 2016b). The ruling restrains the possibility of seeking injunctive relief by specifying a set of requirements that must be fulfilled by the SEP owner. Specifically, before seeking 9 In a landmark decision in Georgia-Pacific Corp. vs United States Plywood Corp - Judge Tenney established 15 factors to be considered for the determination of reasonable royalties; these are known as the Georgia Pacific factors. The pioneer case for FRAND in the U.S. is Microsoft Corp. vs Motorola, Inc. in The court established that royalty rates should be determined as the outcome of a hypothetical bilateral negotiation ex ante to standard setting. 12

14 an injunction the patent holder must inform the implementer about the infringement and must present a detailed offer indicating the royalty rate and the way in which it has been determined. SSOs and innovation The literature has devoted far less attention to the relationship between SSOs membership and firms innovative activities. As suggested by Baron et al. (2014), despite the fact that SSOs are intended as an institution to speed up the standardization process and, as such, to improve market efficiency, they may have undesired effects on the incentives to innovate of their members. Often companies contributing to the standard adhere to informal consortia to supplement the formal standard setting process; the three authors study how these consortia can help coordinating R&D efforts thus mitigating market failures. Using information on a large panel of ICT standards issued between 1992 and 2009, they find that firms tend to innovate more after joining the consortium. However, this effect disappears, or it is even reversed, when the firms R&D incentives are mainly driven by the prospect of licensing a standard essential patent. Blind et al. (2017) study the interplay of standards and governmental regulation on firms innovative efficiency, measured in terms of the resources needed to innovate. The authors use information collected within the 2011 German Community Innovation Survey and find that regulation and standards have opposing effects which depend on the degree of uncertainty characterizing the environment within which companies operate. They distinguish markets with low or high degree of uncertainty on the basis of an index combining different sources of uncertainty (competition, consumer behavior, technological complexity). The authors find that, in the case of low market uncertainty, standards reduce innovation efficiency while regulation increases it; with high market uncertainty, results are reversed. 7. The market for ideas One of the crucial roles of patents is to favour the market for ideas, that is a place where the right to use a technology is traded, either via licensing or via outright sale. As already mentioned (see Section 3), Green and Scotchmer (1995) show that an efficient patent market guarantees the correct R&D incentives for the whole sequence of innovators. It is difficult to estimate accurately the overall magnitude of the market for ideas as most transactions are confidential. Nevertheless, available evidence suggests that it has grown considerably during the last years (see Arora and Gambardella, 2010 for a survey). Recent figures reveal that cross-country licensing for patents, trademarks and copyright, including transactions among affiliated entities, increased in the OECD area by an average annual rate of 10.6% between 2000 and 2010 (OECD, 2012). Athreye and Yang (2011), updating a previous work by Athreye and Cantwell (2007), show that overall license and royalty payments reached approximately USD 180 billion in In a survey with a sample of more than 2,000 European and Japanese firms, Zuniga and Guellec (2008) find that about a fifth of European companies and a fourth of the Japanese ones license patents to non-affiliated firms. The two authors also observe that, between 2003 and 2006, licensing has increased in importance for about 45% of the firms in the sample. Akcigit et al. (2015) measure the extent of the patent market by focusing on outright sales. They estimate firm-by-firm transfers using information from the NBER-USPTO patent grant database and from the patent reassignment data hosted in Google Patents Beta. They find that, among the patents registered at the USPTO during the period , 16% were traded; this number goes up to 20% among domestic patents. Looking at the sectorial level, ICT firms appear 13

15 to be involved in technology licensing much more than companies in other sectors (Sheehan et al., 2004). Interestingly, according to Hagiu et al. (2011) individual inventors and SMEs seem to be the least able to access patent markets. By combining information taken from several different public sources, the authors find that, indeed, in the United States, large companies contribute about to 40% of all patents but obtain 99% of the revenues generated through licensing. Therefore, it seems that market distortions reduce the ability of small firms and inventors to monetize the value of their patents. Despite the impressive growth registered during the recent years, the market for ideas appears to be prone to failures. Drawing from the literature on market design, Gans and Stern (2010) identify several potential inefficiencies characterizing the patent market. First of all, patents are inherently difficult to evaluate; parties may have disparate expectations about their value and little information can be drawn from previous market transactions. Moreover, with highly fragmented IP rights, as in ICTs, the acquisition of a single patent is of little value, unless prospective buyers already own complementary patents. These complementarity/portfolio effects reduce the number of potential buyers, thus making the market less thick. In addition to that, the cost of searching and identifying potential buyers or sellers of the technology is substantial; this is all the more so as the number of patents reading on the relevant technologies/products gets larger. Finally, negotiations take place in the shadow of litigation and licensing terms heavily depend on the opportunity cost of going to trial for the involved parties rather than on the actual value of the patent. As a consequence of these inefficiencies, it is frequently mentioned that potentially valuable patents might not be commercialized and fully exploited for innovation (Giuri et al., 2015). Moving from these considerations, Agrawal et al. (2015) employ licensing data from the 2006 survey conducted by the Licensing Foundation in the US and Canada to estimate the main reasons of deal failures in the market for ideas. They identify three stages in the licensing process, the initial stage of identification of the prospective buyers/sellers, the intermediate stage where negotiations occur and the last stage where the agreement is reached. The authors find that significant failures occur especially in the first stage where the lack of market thickness prevents identifying potential buyers/sellers, and in the last stage because of the classical Arrow s appropriability problem which makes sellers hesitating in providing full information about the technology (Arrow, 1962). Frictions at the initial stages of the licensing process associated with large search costs and pervasive information asymmetries are found to play a major role also in Gambardella et al. (2007). 10 The lack of transparency regarding patent transactions has been recognized by industry experts and analysts as one of the major impediments to the development of the market for ideas. As a matter of fact, when intellectual property changes hands, there is often no record of the transaction; this generates uncertainty over who is in the market, what their intentions are, and whether their property rights are already licensed. This lack of transparency leads potentially to more infringements, higher transaction costs, and larger expenses for dispute resolution (Giuri et al., 2015). This issue is so relevant that the USPTO has recently made available on Google Patents information on reassignments; these data inform about changes in patent ownership since the year 1980 (see 10 Comino et al. (2011) develop a game-theoretic model to show that even in the presence of a weak form of asymmetric information - the inability of the early inventor to observe the timing of the investment of the follow-on inventor innovators are prevented from negotiating efficiently. 14

Standard-Essential Patents

Standard-Essential Patents Standard-Essential Patents Richard Gilbert University of California, Berkeley Symposium on Management of Intellectual Property in Standard-Setting Processes October 3-4, 2012 Washington, D.C. The Smartphone

More information

IS STANDARDIZATION FOR AUTONOMOUS CARS AROUND THE CORNER? By Shervin Pishevar

IS STANDARDIZATION FOR AUTONOMOUS CARS AROUND THE CORNER? By Shervin Pishevar IS STANDARDIZATION FOR AUTONOMOUS CARS AROUND THE CORNER? By Shervin Pishevar Given the recent focus on self-driving cars, it is only a matter of time before the industry begins to consider setting technical

More information

Slide 25 Advantages and disadvantages of patenting

Slide 25 Advantages and disadvantages of patenting Slide 25 Advantages and disadvantages of patenting Patent owners can exclude others from using their inventions. If the invention relates to a product or process feature, this may mean competitors cannot

More information

Patents: Who uses them, for what and what are they worth?

Patents: Who uses them, for what and what are they worth? Patents: Who uses them, for what and what are they worth? Ashish Arora Heinz School Carnegie Mellon University Major theme: conflicting evidence Value of patents Received wisdom in economics and management

More information

Complementarity, Fragmentation and the Effects of Patent Thicket

Complementarity, Fragmentation and the Effects of Patent Thicket Complementarity, Fragmentation and the Effects of Patent Thicket Sadao Nagaoka Hitotsubashi University / Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry Yoichiro Nishimura Kanagawa University November

More information

Issues and Possible Reforms in the U.S. Patent System

Issues and Possible Reforms in the U.S. Patent System Issues and Possible Reforms in the U.S. Patent System Bronwyn H. Hall Professor in the Graduate School University of California at Berkeley Overview Economics of patents and innovations Changes to US patent

More information

Patents and Standards

Patents and Standards Ref. Ares(2014)917891-25/03/2014 Patents and Standards A modern framework for IPR-based standardization Executive Summary A study prepared for the European Commission Directorate-General for Enterprise

More information

Patents as a regulatory tool

Patents as a regulatory tool Patents as a regulatory tool What patent offices can do to promote innovation UNECE Team of Specialists on Intellectual Property 'Intellectual Property and Competition Policy' Geneva, 21 June 2012 Nikolaus

More information

Setting out the EU approach to Standard Essential Patents:

Setting out the EU approach to Standard Essential Patents: Setting out the EU approach to Standard Essential Patents: Update on the European Commission s work Anne von Zukowski (GROW F3) 9th GRUR Int./JIPLP Joint Seminar The EU approach to SEPs HUAWEI, its aftermath

More information

INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY (IP) SME SCOREBOARD 2016

INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY (IP) SME SCOREBOARD 2016 www.euipo.europa.eu INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY (IP) SME SCOREBOARD 2016 Executive Summary JUNE 2016 www.euipo.europa.eu INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY (IP) SME SCOREBOARD 2016 Commissioned to GfK Belgium by the European

More information

INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY (IP) SME SCOREBOARD 2016

INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY (IP) SME SCOREBOARD 2016 www.euipo.europa.eu INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY (IP) SME SCOREBOARD 2016 Executive Summary JUNE 2016 www.euipo.europa.eu INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY (IP) SME SCOREBOARD 2016 Commissioned to GfK Belgium by the European

More information

Comments on the Commission s draft Guidelines on the application of Article 101 TFEU on technology transfer agreements

Comments on the Commission s draft Guidelines on the application of Article 101 TFEU on technology transfer agreements 16 May 2013 Comments on the Commission s draft Guidelines on the application of Article 101 TFEU on technology transfer agreements I. Introduction France Brevets is grateful to be given the opportunity

More information

How Patent Damages Skew Licensing Markets

How Patent Damages Skew Licensing Markets How Patent Damages Skew Licensing Markets Erik Hovenkamp & Jonathan Masur Forthcoming, Review of Litigation Patent Damages Generally Computing patent damages is hard. Courts use the Georgia-Pacific factors

More information

SHORT SUMMARY REPORT OF THE WORKSHOP ON GENETIC INVENTIONS, INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS AND LICENSING PRACTICES

SHORT SUMMARY REPORT OF THE WORKSHOP ON GENETIC INVENTIONS, INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS AND LICENSING PRACTICES SHORT SUMMARY REPORT OF THE WORKSHOP ON GENETIC INVENTIONS, INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS AND LICENSING PRACTICES Held in Berlin, Germany 24 and 25 January 2002 1 I. The Berlin Experts Workshop On January

More information

Economics of IPRs and patents

Economics of IPRs and patents Economics of IPRs and patents TIK, UiO 2016 Bart Verspagen UNU-MERIT, Maastricht verspagen@merit.unu.edu 3. Intellectual property rights The logic of IPRs, in particular patents The economic design of

More information

Issues at the Intersection of IP and Competition Policy

Issues at the Intersection of IP and Competition Policy Issues at the Intersection of IP and Competition Policy WIPO Symposium 11 May 2010 Jeremy West OECD Competition Division jeremy.west@oecd.org The Big Picture IP and competition policy are mostly complementary,

More information

Public Hearings Concerning the Evolving Intellectual Property Marketplace

Public Hearings Concerning the Evolving Intellectual Property Marketplace [Billing Code: 6750-01-S] FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION Public Hearings Concerning the Evolving Intellectual Property Marketplace AGENCY: Federal Trade Commission. ACTION: Notice of Public Hearings SUMMARY:

More information

Patenting Strategies. The First Steps. Patenting Strategies / Bernhard Nussbaumer, 12/17/2009 1

Patenting Strategies. The First Steps. Patenting Strategies / Bernhard Nussbaumer, 12/17/2009 1 Patenting Strategies The First Steps Patenting Strategies / Bernhard Nussbaumer, 12/17/2009 1 Contents 1. The pro-patent era 2. Main drivers 3. The value of patents 4. Patent management 5. The strategic

More information

Business Method Patents, Innovation, and Policy. Bronwyn H. Hall UC Berkeley and NBER

Business Method Patents, Innovation, and Policy. Bronwyn H. Hall UC Berkeley and NBER Business Method Patents, Innovation, and Policy Bronwyn H. Hall UC Berkeley and NBER Outline What is a business method patent? Patents and innovation Patent quality Survey of policy recommendations The

More information

The EX ANTE DEBATE. Presented by. Monica M. Barone Sr. Legal Counsel Qualcomm. Monica M. Barone Sr. Legal Counsel Qualcomm

The EX ANTE DEBATE. Presented by. Monica M. Barone Sr. Legal Counsel Qualcomm. Monica M. Barone Sr. Legal Counsel Qualcomm The EX ANTE DEBATE Presented by Monica M. Barone Sr. Legal Counsel Qualcomm Monica M. Barone Sr. Legal Counsel Qualcomm ANSI Legal Issues Forum: Patented Technology in Standards October 13, 2011 1 Standards

More information

Patents and innovation (and competition) Bronwyn H. Hall UC Berkeley, U of Maastricht, NBER, and IFS London

Patents and innovation (and competition) Bronwyn H. Hall UC Berkeley, U of Maastricht, NBER, and IFS London Patents and innovation (and competition) Bronwyn H. Hall UC Berkeley, U of Maastricht, NBER, and IFS London Patent system as viewed by a two-handed economist Effects on Innovation Competition Positive

More information

Patents, Standards and the Global Economy

Patents, Standards and the Global Economy Patents, Standards and the Global Economy Nikolaus Thumm 5 th Workshop The Output of R&D activities: Harnessing the Power of Patents Data Seville, 19-20 September 2013 SEPs = Standard Essential Patents

More information

The Interplay between Patents and Standards: Empirical Evidence

The Interplay between Patents and Standards: Empirical Evidence The Interplay between Patents and Standards: Empirical Evidence Prof. Dr. Knut Blind Technische Universität Berlin, Chair of Innovation Economics Rotterdam School of Management, Chair of Standardisation

More information

Intellectual property and competition policy

Intellectual property and competition policy EUROPEAN COMMISSION Joaquín Almunia Vice President of the European Commission responsible for Competition Policy Intellectual property and competition policy IP Summit 2013 (Paris) 9 December 2013 SPEECH/13/1042

More information

The Patent Policy Debate in the High Tech World: A Literature Review

The Patent Policy Debate in the High Tech World: A Literature Review The Patent Policy Debate in the High Tech World: A Literature Review Kirti Gupta January 30, 2013 Abstract Patents have great public visibility these days; questions and opinions abound on the fairness

More information

Strategic use of patents: The case of patent trolls

Strategic use of patents: The case of patent trolls Strategic use of patents: The case of patent trolls Pénin Julien BETA Université de Strasbourg penin@unistra.fr DIMETIC Lecture March, 2010 Overview Patents as strategic instruments Much more than mere

More information

Guidelines on Standardization and Patent Pool Arrangements

Guidelines on Standardization and Patent Pool Arrangements Guidelines on Standardization and Patent Pool Arrangements Part 1 Introduction In industries experiencing innovation and technical change, such as the information technology sector, it is important to

More information

Introduction to the Special Section on Patent Use. (forthcoming, Research Policy, September 2016)

Introduction to the Special Section on Patent Use. (forthcoming, Research Policy, September 2016) Introduction to the Special Section on Patent Use (forthcoming, Research Policy, September 2016) Ashish Arora (Duke University, Durham NC, and NBER, USA) Suma Athreye (Brunel University, UK and UNU-MERIT;

More information

Patent Pools and Patent Inflation An empirical analysis of contemporary patent pools

Patent Pools and Patent Inflation An empirical analysis of contemporary patent pools Patent Pools and Patent Inflation An empirical analysis of contemporary patent pools Tim Pohlmann Justus Baron CERNA-MINES, ParisTech Patent Statistics For Decision Makers, Paris, 2012 Introduction Joint

More information

Business Method Patents, Innovation, and Policy

Business Method Patents, Innovation, and Policy Business Method Patents, Innovation, and Policy Bronwyn H. Hall UC Berkeley, NBER, IFS, Scuola Sant Anna Anna, and TSP International Outline (paper, not talk) What is a business method patent? Patents

More information

The role of Intellectual Property (IP) in R&D-based companies: Setting the context of the relative importance and Management of IP

The role of Intellectual Property (IP) in R&D-based companies: Setting the context of the relative importance and Management of IP The role of Intellectual Property (IP) in R&D-based companies: Setting the context of the relative importance and Management of IP Thomas Gering Ph.D. Technology Transfer & Scientific Co-operation Joint

More information

Presentation to NAS Committee on IP Management in Standards-Setting Processes. Dan Bart President and CEO Valley View Corporation November 4, 2011

Presentation to NAS Committee on IP Management in Standards-Setting Processes. Dan Bart President and CEO Valley View Corporation November 4, 2011 Presentation to NAS Committee on IP Management in Standards-Setting Processes Dan Bart President and CEO Valley View Corporation November 4, 2011 Who is Dan Bart? Current Chairman of the ANSI IPR Policy

More information

UNCITRAL Third International Colloquium on Secured Transactions Session on Contractual Guide on IP Licensing (Vienna, March 3, 2010)

UNCITRAL Third International Colloquium on Secured Transactions Session on Contractual Guide on IP Licensing (Vienna, March 3, 2010) UNCITRAL Third International Colloquium on Secured Transactions Session on Contractual Guide on IP Licensing (Vienna, March 3, 2010) Basic contractual requirements on PATENT LICENSING Laurent Manderieux

More information

FTC Panel on Markets for IP and technology

FTC Panel on Markets for IP and technology FTC Panel on Markets for IP and technology Bronwyn H. Hall UC Berkeley 4 May 2009 Topics Non-practicing entities Independent invention/prior user rights Data needs May 2009 FTC Hearings - Berkeley 2 1

More information

April 21, By to:

April 21, By  to: April 21, 2017 Mr. Qiu Yang Office of the Anti-Monopoly Commission Of the State Council of the People s Republic of China No. 2 East Chang an Avenue, Beijing P.R. China 100731 By Email to: qiuyang@mofcom.gov.cn

More information

Comments of Cisco Systems, Inc.

Comments of Cisco Systems, Inc. Comments of Cisco Systems, Inc. in response to Office of Management and Budget Request for Comments Regarding Proposed Revision of OMB Circular No. A-119: Federal Participation in the Development and Use

More information

"Competition Policy and Intellectual Property Rights in the Republic of Latvia since 1991" (the working title)

Competition Policy and Intellectual Property Rights in the Republic of Latvia since 1991 (the working title) "Competition Policy and Intellectual Property Rights in the Republic of Latvia since 1991" (the working title) Research Proposal for the Doctoral Course at the "Ostsee-Kolleg: Baltic Sea School Berlin",

More information

Under the Patronage of His Highness Sayyid Faisal bin Ali Al Said Minister for National Heritage and Culture

Under the Patronage of His Highness Sayyid Faisal bin Ali Al Said Minister for National Heritage and Culture ORIGINAL: English DATE: February 1999 E SULTANATE OF OMAN WORLD INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY ORGANIZATION Under the Patronage of His Highness Sayyid Faisal bin Ali Al Said Minister for National Heritage and Culture

More information

Can t we all just get along? IPRs, standards, interoperability, governance and cooperation

Can t we all just get along? IPRs, standards, interoperability, governance and cooperation Can t we all just get along? IPRs, standards, interoperability, governance and cooperation Knut Blind Chair of Innovation Economics at Berlin University of Technology Head of Competence Center Regulation

More information

Strategic Use of Patents

Strategic Use of Patents Strategic Use of Patents Bronwyn H. Hall UC Berkeley and Maastricht University Background literature Study by Dietmar Harhoff, Bronwyn H. Hall, Georg von Graevenitz, Karin Hoisl, and Stefan Wagner for

More information

Social returns to direct private innovation support: the patent system

Social returns to direct private innovation support: the patent system Social returns to direct private innovation support: the patent system Bhaven N Sampat (Columbia University and NBER) 12/15/16 Senate Judiciary Study #1 (December 20, 1956) Senate Judiciary Study #1 (December

More information

The role of IP in economic development: the case of China

The role of IP in economic development: the case of China The role of IP in economic development: the case of China Albert G. Hu Department of Economics National University of Singapore Prepared for ARTNeT / WTO Research Workshop on Emerging Trade Issues in Asia

More information

The high cost of standardization How to reward innovators

The high cost of standardization How to reward innovators The high cost of standardization How to reward innovators Dr. Matteo Sabattini CTO, Sisvel Group London, October 13,2015 www.sisvel.com 1 THE SISVEL GROUP 30+ YEARS OF EXCELLENCE IN LICENSING 100+ ENGINEERS,

More information

Globalisation increasingly affects how companies in OECD countries

Globalisation increasingly affects how companies in OECD countries ISBN 978-92-64-04767-9 Open Innovation in Global Networks OECD 2008 Executive Summary Globalisation increasingly affects how companies in OECD countries operate, compete and innovate, both at home and

More information

Cover Page. The handle holds various files of this Leiden University dissertation.

Cover Page. The handle   holds various files of this Leiden University dissertation. Cover Page The handle http://hdl.handle.net/1887/50157 holds various files of this Leiden University dissertation. Author: Mair, C.S. Title: Taking technological infrastructure seriously Issue Date: 2017-06-29

More information

Patent Statistics as an Innovation Indicator Lecture 3.1

Patent Statistics as an Innovation Indicator Lecture 3.1 as an Innovation Indicator Lecture 3.1 Fabrizio Pompei Department of Economics University of Perugia Economics of Innovation (2016/2017) (II Semester, 2017) Pompei Patents Academic Year 2016/2017 1 / 27

More information

U.S. Patent-Antitrust Interface. Alden F. Abbott, Heritage Foundation Oxford Competition Law Centre June 28, 2014

U.S. Patent-Antitrust Interface. Alden F. Abbott, Heritage Foundation Oxford Competition Law Centre June 28, 2014 U.S. Patent-Antitrust Interface Alden F. Abbott, Heritage Foundation Oxford Competition Law Centre June 28, 2014 Introduction My thesis is that antitrust law has gradually weakened U.S. patent rights in

More information

1. Recognizing that some of the barriers that impede the diffusion of green technologies include:

1. Recognizing that some of the barriers that impede the diffusion of green technologies include: DATE: OCTOBER 21, 2011 WIPO GREEN THE SUSTAINABLE TECHNOLOGY MARKETPLACE CONCEPT DOCUMENT EXECUTIVE SUMMARY 1. Recognizing that some of the barriers that impede the diffusion of green technologies include:

More information

Used and Unused patents

Used and Unused patents Used and Unused patents Salvatore Torrisi Department of Management University of Bologna torrisi@unibo.it I nnovation in a European digital single market: the role of patents, Bruxelles 17 March 2015 17/03/2015

More information

Alternatives to Ex Ante Disclosure

Alternatives to Ex Ante Disclosure Alternatives to Ex Ante Disclosure Presented by Michael A. Lindsay Partner, DORSEY & WHITNEY LLP ANSI Legal Issues Forum: Patented Technology in Standards October 13, 2011 1 Overview Policy for ex ante

More information

NPRNet Workshop May 3-4, 2001, Paris. Discussion Models of Research Funding. Bronwyn H. Hall

NPRNet Workshop May 3-4, 2001, Paris. Discussion Models of Research Funding. Bronwyn H. Hall NPRNet Workshop May 3-4, 2001, Paris Discussion Models of Research Funding Bronwyn H. Hall All four papers in this section are concerned with models of the performance of scientific research under various

More information

Getting the Most From Your IP Budget: Strategies for IP Portfolio Management and Litigation Avoidance

Getting the Most From Your IP Budget: Strategies for IP Portfolio Management and Litigation Avoidance Getting the Most From Your IP Budget: Strategies for IP Portfolio Management and Litigation Avoidance March 19, 2009 A Web conference hosted by Foley & Lardner LLP Welcome Moderator Andrew Rawlins, Partner,

More information

The Impact of Patent Pools on Further Innovation. Thomas D. Jeitschko* & Nanyun Zhang** March 8, Preliminary and Incomplete; please do not cite.

The Impact of Patent Pools on Further Innovation. Thomas D. Jeitschko* & Nanyun Zhang** March 8, Preliminary and Incomplete; please do not cite. The Impact of Patent Pools on Further Innovation Thomas D. Jeitschko* & Nanyun Zhang** March 8, 2012 Preliminary and Incomplete; please do not cite. Any comments and suggestions are welcome and appreciated!

More information

Licensing or Not Licensing?:

Licensing or Not Licensing?: RIETI Discussion Paper Series 06-E-021 Licensing or Not Licensing?: Empirical Analysis on Strategic Use of Patent in Japanese Firms MOTOHASHI Kazuyuki RIETI The Research Institute of Economy, Trade and

More information

Fact Sheet IP specificities in research for the benefit of SMEs

Fact Sheet IP specificities in research for the benefit of SMEs European IPR Helpdesk Fact Sheet IP specificities in research for the benefit of SMEs June 2015 1 Introduction... 1 1. Actions for the benefit of SMEs... 2 1.1 Research for SMEs... 2 1.2 Research for SME-Associations...

More information

Comments of the AMERICAN INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW ASSOCIATION. Regarding

Comments of the AMERICAN INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW ASSOCIATION. Regarding Comments of the AMERICAN INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW ASSOCIATION Regarding THE ISSUES PAPER OF THE AUSTRALIAN ADVISORY COUNCIL ON INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY CONCERNING THE PATENTING OF BUSINESS SYSTEMS ISSUED

More information

WIPO-WASME Program on Practical Intellectual Property Rights Issues for Entrepreneurs, Economists, Bankers, Lawyers and Accountants

WIPO-WASME Program on Practical Intellectual Property Rights Issues for Entrepreneurs, Economists, Bankers, Lawyers and Accountants WIPO-WASME Program on Practical Intellectual Property Rights Issues for Entrepreneurs, Economists, Bankers, Lawyers and Accountants Topic 12 Managing IP in Public-Private Partnerships, Strategic Alliances,

More information

Globalizing IPR Protection: How Important Might RTAs Be?

Globalizing IPR Protection: How Important Might RTAs Be? Globalizing IPR Protection: How Important Might RTAs Be? Keith Maskus, University of Colorado Boulder (keith.maskus@colorado.edu) NAS Innovation Policy Forum National and International IP Policies and

More information

The Causal Effect of Essential Patents on Follow-on Innovation Related to Technology Standards

The Causal Effect of Essential Patents on Follow-on Innovation Related to Technology Standards The Causal Effect of Essential Patents on Follow-on Innovation Related to Technology Standards Justus Baron Northwestern University Searle Center on Law, Regulation and Economic Growth October 7, 2016

More information

WIPO REGIONAL SEMINAR ON SUPPORT SERVICES FOR INVENTORS, VALUATION AND COMMERCIALIZATION OF INVENTIONS AND RESEARCH RESULTS

WIPO REGIONAL SEMINAR ON SUPPORT SERVICES FOR INVENTORS, VALUATION AND COMMERCIALIZATION OF INVENTIONS AND RESEARCH RESULTS ORIGINAL: English DATE: November 1998 E TECHNOLOGY APPLICATION AND PROMOTION INSTITUTE WORLD INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY ORGANIZATION WIPO REGIONAL SEMINAR ON SUPPORT SERVICES FOR INVENTORS, VALUATION AND COMMERCIALIZATION

More information

The Economics of Patents Lecture 3

The Economics of Patents Lecture 3 The Economics of Patents Lecture 3 Fabrizio Pompei Department of Economics University of Perugia Economics of Innovation (2016/2017) (II Semester, 2017) Pompei Patents Academic Year 2016/2017 1 / 29 Contents

More information

Enforcement of Intellectual Property Rights Frequently Asked Questions

Enforcement of Intellectual Property Rights Frequently Asked Questions EUROPEAN COMMISSION MEMO Brussels/Strasbourg, 1 July 2014 Enforcement of Intellectual Property Rights Frequently Asked Questions See also IP/14/760 I. EU Action Plan on enforcement of Intellectual Property

More information

WIPO-IFIA INTERNATIONAL SYMPOSIUM ON THE COMMERCIALIZATION OF INVENTIONS IN THE GLOBAL MARKET

WIPO-IFIA INTERNATIONAL SYMPOSIUM ON THE COMMERCIALIZATION OF INVENTIONS IN THE GLOBAL MARKET ORIGINAL: English DATE: December 2002 E INTERNATIONAL FEDERATION OF INVENTORS ASSOCIATIONS WORLD INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY ORGANIZATION WIPO-IFIA INTERNATIONAL SYMPOSIUM ON THE COMMERCIALIZATION OF INVENTIONS

More information

Prepared for BCLT IP and Entrepreneurship Symposium Boalt Hall March, 2008 Scott Stern, Northwestern and NBER

Prepared for BCLT IP and Entrepreneurship Symposium Boalt Hall March, 2008 Scott Stern, Northwestern and NBER Should Technology Entrepreneurs Care about Patent Reform? Prepared for BCLT IP and Entrepreneurship Symposium Boalt Hall March, 2008 Scott Stern, Northwestern and NBER Magic Patents From a classical perspective,

More information

CIFRA: Challenging the ICT Patent Framework for Responsible Innovation

CIFRA: Challenging the ICT Patent Framework for Responsible Innovation Grant Agreement No.731940 Research and Innovation Action Call: H2020-ICT-35-2016 CIFRA: Challenging the ICT Patent Framework for Responsible Innovation D3.3: (Preliminary) Policy Paper on potential new

More information

The Role of Effective Intellectual Property Management in Enhancing the Competitiveness of Small and Medium-sized Enterprises (SMEs)

The Role of Effective Intellectual Property Management in Enhancing the Competitiveness of Small and Medium-sized Enterprises (SMEs) The Role of Effective Intellectual Property Management in Enhancing the Competitiveness of Small and Medium-sized Enterprises (SMEs) Training of Trainers Program on Effective Intellectual Property Asset

More information

Fiscal 2007 Environmental Technology Verification Pilot Program Implementation Guidelines

Fiscal 2007 Environmental Technology Verification Pilot Program Implementation Guidelines Fifth Edition Fiscal 2007 Environmental Technology Verification Pilot Program Implementation Guidelines April 2007 Ministry of the Environment, Japan First Edition: June 2003 Second Edition: May 2004 Third

More information

Lexis PSL Competition Practice Note

Lexis PSL Competition Practice Note Lexis PSL Competition Practice Note Research and development Produced in partnership with K&L Gates LLP Research and Development (R&D ) are under which two or more parties agree to jointly execute research

More information

IP and Technology Management for Universities

IP and Technology Management for Universities IP and Technology Management for Universities Yumiko Hamano Senior Program Officer WIPO University Initiative Innovation and Technology Transfer Section, Patent Division, WIPO Outline! University and IP!

More information

UNCTAD Ad Hoc Expert Meeting on the Green Economy: Trade and Sustainable Development Implications November

UNCTAD Ad Hoc Expert Meeting on the Green Economy: Trade and Sustainable Development Implications November UNCTAD Ad Hoc Expert Meeting on the Green Economy: Trade and Sustainable Development Implications 8-10 November Panel 3: ENHANCING TECHNOLOGY ACCESS AND TRANSFER Good morning Ladies and Gentlemen. On behalf

More information

Executive summary. AI is the new electricity. I can hardly imagine an industry which is not going to be transformed by AI.

Executive summary. AI is the new electricity. I can hardly imagine an industry which is not going to be transformed by AI. Executive summary Artificial intelligence (AI) is increasingly driving important developments in technology and business, from autonomous vehicles to medical diagnosis to advanced manufacturing. As AI

More information

INTRODUCTION Standards have become the foundation for information exchange, communications, and entertainment. Today, as in the past, governments deve

INTRODUCTION Standards have become the foundation for information exchange, communications, and entertainment. Today, as in the past, governments deve Standards have become the foundation for information exchange, communications, and entertainment. Today, as in the past, governments develop or reference standards to protect the safety, security, and

More information

Post-Grant Patent Review Conference on Patent Reform Berkeley Center for Law and Technology April 16, 2004

Post-Grant Patent Review Conference on Patent Reform Berkeley Center for Law and Technology April 16, 2004 Post-Grant Patent Review Conference on Patent Reform Berkeley Center for Law and Technology April 16, 2004 Bronwyn H. Hall UC Berkeley and NBER Overview Heterogeneity More patents not necessarily better

More information

Does pro-patent policy spur innovation? : A case of software industry in Japan

Does pro-patent policy spur innovation? : A case of software industry in Japan Does pro-patent policy spur innovation? : A case of software industry in Japan Masayo Kani and Kazuyuki Motohashi (*) Department of Technology Management for Innovation, University of Tokyo 7-3-1 Hongo

More information

The Role of the Intellectual Property Office

The Role of the Intellectual Property Office The Role of the Intellectual Property Office Intellectual Property Office is an operating name of the Patent Office The Hargreaves Review In 2011, Professor Ian Hargreaves published his review of intellectual

More information

Statement by the BIAC Committee on Technology and Industry on THE IMPACT OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY PROTECTION ON INNOVATION AND TECHNOLOGY DEVELOPMENT

Statement by the BIAC Committee on Technology and Industry on THE IMPACT OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY PROTECTION ON INNOVATION AND TECHNOLOGY DEVELOPMENT Business and Industry Advisory Committee to the OECD OECD Comité Consultatif Economique et Industriel Auprès de l l OCDE Statement by the BIAC Committee on Technology and Industry on THE IMPACT OF INTELLECTUAL

More information

Science and Innovation Policies at the Digital Age. Dominique Guellec Science and Technology Policy OECD

Science and Innovation Policies at the Digital Age. Dominique Guellec Science and Technology Policy OECD Science and Innovation Policies at the Digital Age Dominique Guellec Science and Technology Policy OECD Grenoble, December 2 2016 Structure of the Presentation What does digitalisation mean for science

More information

Establishing a Development Agenda for the World Intellectual Property Organization

Establishing a Development Agenda for the World Intellectual Property Organization 1 Establishing a Development Agenda for the World Intellectual Property Organization to be submitted by Brazil and Argentina to the 40 th Series of Meetings of the Assemblies of the Member States of WIPO

More information

National Intellectual Property Systems, Innovation and Economic Development Framework for Country Analysis. Dominique Guellec

National Intellectual Property Systems, Innovation and Economic Development Framework for Country Analysis. Dominique Guellec National Intellectual Property Systems, Innovation and Economic Development Framework for Country Analysis Dominique Guellec How can IP systems best be mobilised for innovation in middle-income economies?

More information

DEFENSIVE PUBLICATION IN FRANCE

DEFENSIVE PUBLICATION IN FRANCE DEFENSIVE PUBLICATION IN FRANCE A SURVEY ON THE USAGE OF THE IP STRATEGY DEFENSIVE PUBLICATION AUGUST 2012 Eva Gimello Spécialisée en droit de la Propriété Industrielle Université Paris XI Felix Coxwell

More information

CPI Antitrust Chronicle October 2013 (1)

CPI Antitrust Chronicle October 2013 (1) CPI Antitrust Chronicle October 2013 (1) Standard Setting: Should There Be a Level Playing Field for All FRAND Commitments? Nadia Soboleva & Lawrence Wu NERA Economic Consulting www.competitionpolicyinternational.com

More information

TOOL #21. RESEARCH & INNOVATION

TOOL #21. RESEARCH & INNOVATION TOOL #21. RESEARCH & INNOVATION 1. INTRODUCTION This research and innovation Tool provides clear guidelines for analysing the interaction between new or revised EU legislation (including spending programmes)

More information

STANDARDS SETTING, STANDARDS DEVELOPMENT AND DIVISION OF THE GAINS FROM STANDARDIZATION

STANDARDS SETTING, STANDARDS DEVELOPMENT AND DIVISION OF THE GAINS FROM STANDARDIZATION STANDARDS SETTING, STANDARDS DEVELOPMENT AND DIVISION OF THE GAINS FROM STANDARDIZATION By David J. Teece 1 and Edward F. Sherry 2 Consider the degree of technology incorporated into various compatibility/interoperability

More information

demonstrator approach real market conditions would be useful to provide a unified partner search instrument for the CIP programme

demonstrator approach real market conditions  would be useful to provide a unified partner search instrument for the CIP programme Contribution by the Ministry of Industry and Trade of the Czech Republic to the public consultations on a successor programme to the Competitiveness and Innovation Framework Programme (CIP) 2007-2013 Given

More information

WHO workshop on IP and Vaccines. Geneva 19 th -20 th April Introduction to the IP issues Christopher Garrison Consultant to WHO

WHO workshop on IP and Vaccines. Geneva 19 th -20 th April Introduction to the IP issues Christopher Garrison Consultant to WHO WHO workshop on IP and Vaccines Geneva 19 th -20 th April 2004 Introduction to the IP issues Christopher Garrison Consultant to WHO Vaccine access, R&D and technology transfer issues are intimately linked

More information

Kauffman Dissertation Executive Summary

Kauffman Dissertation Executive Summary Kauffman Dissertation Executive Summary Part of the Ewing Marion Kauffman Foundation s Emerging Scholars initiative, the Program recognizes exceptional doctoral students and their universities. The annual

More information

Global patent warming? Number of claims filed at 3 patent offices, (M),

Global patent warming? Number of claims filed at 3 patent offices, (M), The Quality Factor in Patent Systems Intellectual Capital for Communities in the Knowledge Economy Nations, Regions, Cities and Emerging Communities, IC6 Paris, The World Bank Bruno van Pottelsberghe Professor,

More information

NEW TREATY DEVELOPMENT AND HARMONIZATION OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW

NEW TREATY DEVELOPMENT AND HARMONIZATION OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW NEW TREATY DEVELOPMENT AND HARMONIZATION OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW The prolonged negotiation of the Agreement on Trade Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPs Agreement) might have suggested

More information

Building a Competitive Edge: Protecting Inventions by Patents and Utility Models

Building a Competitive Edge: Protecting Inventions by Patents and Utility Models Topic 4 Building a Competitive Edge: Protecting Inventions by Patents and Utility Models Training of Trainer s Program, Teheran 8 June 2015 By Matthias Kuhn, MBA University of Geneva, Unitec, Switzerland

More information

FICPI views on a novelty grace period in a global patent system

FICPI views on a novelty grace period in a global patent system FICPI views on a novelty grace period in a global patent system Jan Modin, CET special reporter, international patents Tegernsee Symposium Tokyo 10 July 2014 1 FICPI short presentation IP attorneys in

More information

To be presented at Fifth Annual Conference on Innovation and Entrepreneurship, Northwestern University, Friday, June 15, 2012

To be presented at Fifth Annual Conference on Innovation and Entrepreneurship, Northwestern University, Friday, June 15, 2012 To be presented at Fifth Annual Conference on Innovation and Entrepreneurship, Northwestern University, Friday, June 15, 2012 Ownership structure of vertical research collaboration: empirical analysis

More information

The Uneasy Future of Software and Business-Method Patents

The Uneasy Future of Software and Business-Method Patents The Uneasy Future of Software and Business-Method Patents SD Times March 24, 2010 Yoches, E. Robert, Arner, Erika Harmon, Dubal, Uttam G. Protecting and enforcing IP rights in a high-speed world The world

More information

Research Collection. Comment on Henkel, J. and F. Jell "Alternative motives to file for patents: profiting from pendency and publication.

Research Collection. Comment on Henkel, J. and F. Jell Alternative motives to file for patents: profiting from pendency and publication. Research Collection Report Comment on Henkel, J. and F. Jell "Alternative motives to file for patents: profiting from pendency and publication Author(s): Mayr, Stefan Publication Date: 2009 Permanent Link:

More information

Carnegie Endowment for International Peace

Carnegie Endowment for International Peace Carnegie Endowment for International Peace How the U.S. and India could Collaborate to Strengthen Their Bilateral Relationship in the Pharmaceutical Sector Second Panel: Exploring the Gilead-India Licensing

More information

Submission to the Productivity Commission inquiry into Intellectual Property Arrangements

Submission to the Productivity Commission inquiry into Intellectual Property Arrangements Submission to the Productivity Commission inquiry into Intellectual Property Arrangements DECEMBER 2015 Business Council of Australia December 2015 1 Contents About this submission 2 Key recommendations

More information

EVCA Strategic Priorities

EVCA Strategic Priorities EVCA Strategic Priorities EVCA Strategic Priorities The following document identifies the strategic priorities for the European Private Equity and Venture Capital Association (EVCA) over the next three

More information

GENEVA STANDING COMMITTEE ON THE LAW OF PATENTS. Thirteenth Session Geneva, March 23 to 27, 2009 STANDARDS AND PATENTS *

GENEVA STANDING COMMITTEE ON THE LAW OF PATENTS. Thirteenth Session Geneva, March 23 to 27, 2009 STANDARDS AND PATENTS * WIPO SCP/13/2. ORIGINAL: English DATE: February 18, 2009 WORLD INTELLECTUAL PROPERT Y O RGANI ZATION GENEVA E STANDING COMMITTEE ON THE LAW OF PATENTS Thirteenth Session Geneva, March 23 to 27, 2009 STANDARDS

More information

Facilitating Technology Transfer and Management of IP Assets:

Facilitating Technology Transfer and Management of IP Assets: Intellectual Property, Technology Transfer and Commercialization Facilitating Technology Transfer and Management of IP Assets: Thailand Experiences Singapore August 27-28, 2014 Mrs. Jiraporn Luengpailin

More information

The Defensive Patent License

The Defensive Patent License The Defensive Patent License JENNIFER M. URBAN CO-AUTHOR: JASON M. SCHULTZ BERKELEY LAW 2013 O Reilly Open Source Conference Portland, Oregondf July 24, 2013 PROBLEM Innovation in the shadow of software

More information

THE AMERICA INVENTS ACT NEW POST-ISSUANCE PATENT OFFICE PROCEEDINGS

THE AMERICA INVENTS ACT NEW POST-ISSUANCE PATENT OFFICE PROCEEDINGS THE AMERICA INVENTS ACT NEW POST-ISSUANCE PATENT OFFICE PROCEEDINGS By Sharon Israel and Kyle Friesen I. Introduction The recently enacted Leahy-Smith America Invents Act ( AIA ) 1 marks the most sweeping

More information