Structural Change and Economic Dynamics

Similar documents
Innovation performances in Europe: a long term perspective

Innovation and demand in industry dynamics

The Macroeconomic Studies on the Benefits of Standards: A Summary, Assessment and Outlook

Competitiveness and innovation in Europe. The dynamics of export success, R&D and new products in EU industries

The interactions between national systems and sectoral patterns of innovation: a cross-country analysis of Pavitt s taxonomy

The interactions between national systems and sectoral patterns of innovation. A cross-country analysis of Pavitt s taxonomy

Firm-Level Determinants of Export Performance: Evidence from the Philippines

TECHNOLOGICAL REGIMES: THEORY AND EVIDENCE

Innovation in Norway in a European Perspective

EU KLEMS WORKING PAPER SERIES Product

Technology and Competitiveness in Vietnam

Oesterreichische Nationalbank. Eurosystem. Workshops Proceedings of OeNB Workshops. Current Issues of Economic Growth. March 5, No.

Offshoring and the Skill Structure of Labour Demand

Patent Statistics as an Innovation Indicator Lecture 3.1

A TAXONOMY OF DIGITAL INTENSIVE SECTORS

Industrial innovation in Finland

SMALL BUSINESS IN INNOVATIVE DEVELOPMENT OF RUSSIA

Evaluation of the gender pay gap in Lithuania

COMPETITIVNESS, INNOVATION AND GROWTH: THE CASE OF MACEDONIA

The Future of Intangibles

Information Technology and the Japanese Growth Recovery

Innovation, IP Choice, and Firm Performance

Why is US Productivity Growth So Slow? Possible Explanations Possible Policy Responses

City-REDI Policy Briefing Series

EUROPEAN MANUFACTURING SURVEY EMS

Innovation in Europe: Where s it going? How does it happen? Stephen Roper Aston Business School, Birmingham, UK

More of the same or something different? Technological originality and novelty in public procurement-related patents

Creativity and Economic Development

An Integrated Industrial Policy for the Globalisation Era

D8.2 Overall impact of the Innovation Union progress as measured in the IU scoreboard

Nordic Journal of Political Economy

CZECH ECONOMY. In 2016 and 1H2017. Section of Industry Economic Analyses Department. Czech Economy

Measuring Romania s Creative Economy

Outline. Patents as indicators. Economic research on patents. What are patent citations? Two types of data. Measuring the returns to innovation (2)

Dr Ioannis Bournakis

Innovation and Growth in the Lagging Regions of Europe. Neil Lee London School of Economics

Observing Science, Technology and Innovation Studies in Russia HSE ISSEK Surveys

Trade Barriers EU-Russia based in technical regulations

E-COMMERCE AS A TOOL FOR DEVELOPMENT : ANALYTICAL AND REGIONAL PERSPECTIVE ARUN JACOB

Information Technology and the Japanese Growth Recovery

OECD s Innovation Strategy: Key Findings and Policy Messages

April Keywords: Imitation; Innovation; R&D-based growth model JEL classification: O32; O40

Measurement and differentiation of knowledge and information flows in Brazilian Local Productive Arrangements

Innovation and economic performance in services: a firm-level analysis

Innovation system research and policy: Where it came from and Where it might go

Knowledge, technology trajectories, and innovation in a developing country context: evidence from a survey of Malaysian firms

Executive Summary World Robotics 2018 Industrial Robots

ASSESSMENT OF DYNAMICS OF THE INDEX OF THE OF THE INNOVATION AND ITS INFLUENCE ON GROSS DOMESTIC PRODUCT OF LATVIA

THE IMPLICATIONS OF THE KNOWLEDGE-BASED ECONOMY FOR FUTURE SCIENCE AND TECHNOLOGY POLICIES

Why is US Productivity Growth So Slow? Possible Explanations Possible Policy Responses

TPS 66. Edition 2 March TPS 66 / Edition: 2 Page 1 of 10

Innovation and the competitiveness of industries: comparing the mainstream and the evolutionary approaches

OECD Science, Technology and Industry Outlook 2008: Highlights

High Technology Indicators Year Final results

tepav April2015 N EVALUATION NOTE Science, Technology and Innovation in G20 Countries Economic Policy Research Foundation of Turkey

THE EVOLUTION OF THE INTERNATIONAL SPATIAL ARCHITECTURE OF CLUSTERING AND VALUE NETWORKS

Web Appendix: Online Reputation Mechanisms and the Decreasing Value of Chain Affiliation

R&D in Low Tech Sectors

Producer Price Index (PPI) Manufacturing )2012=100( First Quarter

TECHNOLOGY, ECONOMIC INTEGRATION AND SOCIAL COHESION

Contents. Acknowledgments

2015 Third Quarter. Manufacturing )2012=100( Preliminary. Producer Price Index (PPI)

INNOVATION AND EXPORT PERFORMANCE: EVIDENCE FROM UK AND GERMAN MANUFACTURING PLANTS

WORKSHOP ON BASIC RESEARCH: POLICY RELEVANT DEFINITIONS AND MEASUREMENT ISSUES PAPER. Holmenkollen Park Hotel, Oslo, Norway October 2001

The production function of top R&D investors: Accounting for size and sector heterogeneity with quantile estimations

FINAL ACTIVITY AND MANAGEMENT REPORT

Linking Technology Areas to Industrial Sectors

Strategic & managerial issues behind technological diversification

The demand-pull effect of public procurement on innovation and industrial renewal

U.S. Employment Growth and Tech Investment: A New Link

Knowledge Protection Capabilities and their Effects on Knowledge Creation and Exploitation in Highand Low-tech Environments

Is Corporate R&D Investment in High Tech Sectors More Effective? Some Guidelines for European Research Policy

Missouri Economic Indicator Brief: Manufacturing Industries

Pecuniary Knowledge Externalities in a New Taxonomy: Knowledge Interactions in a Vertically Integrated System

International Workshop on Economic Census

E-Training on GDP Rebasing

An Estimation of Knowledge Production Function By Industry in Korea 1

Information Societies: Towards a More Useful Concept

Innovation and Collaboration Patterns between Research Establishments

Patents, R&D-Performing Sectors, and the Technology Spillover Effect

COUNTRY SPECIALISATION REPORT

Contact address Statistical Center of Iran (SCI), NO1, Corner of Rahi Mayeri St., Dr. Fatemi Ave, Tehran, ,Iran

Innovation and Knowledge Creation in an Open Economy Canadian Industry and International Implications

Main Features of Advanced Technology Industries in Lithuania

Globalisation increasingly affects how companies in OECD countries

Country Innovation Brief: Costa Rica

Venture capital, Ownership concentration and Enterprise R&D investment

1 Yishun Industrial Street 1 #04-10 A Posh Bizhub Issue No : 7 Singapore Date : 06 September 2016

ISAE - Institute for Studies and Economic Analyses

Measuring Eco-innovation Results from the MEI project René Kemp

Procedia - Social and Behavioral Sciences 195 ( 2015 ) World Conference on Technology, Innovation and Entrepreneurship

INNOVATION DEVELOPMENT SECTORAL TRAJECTORIES OF THE SOUTH RUSSIAN REGIONS Igor ANTONENKO *

Innovation in Belgium: Results from the European innovation survey CIS P a g e

Demographics and Robots by Daron Acemoglu and Pascual Restrepo

INNOVATION AND ECONOMIC GROWTH CASE STUDY CHINA AFTER THE WTO

Technology Licensing

Changing role of the State in Innovative Activity The Indian Experience. Sunil Mani

EUROPEAN INNOVATION MONITORING SYSTEM (ElMS)

Industrial Investment in Research and Development: Trends and Prospects

COUNTRY SPECIALISATION REPORT

Transcription:

Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 22 (2011) 41 53 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Structural Change and Economic Dynamics journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/sced Engines of growth. Innovation and productivity in industry groups Francesco Bogliacino a,b, Mario Pianta c, a European Commission, Joint Research Center - Institute for Perspective Technological Studies, Sevilla, Spain b Universidad EAFIT and Rise Group, Medellin, Colombia c University of Urbino, Italy article info abstract Article history: Received June 2009 Received in revised form October 2010 Accepted November 2010 Available online 25 November 2010 JEL classification: O31 O33 O41 Keywords: Innovation Labour productivity Technological competitiveness Cost competitiveness Industry taxonomies The diversity of technological activities that contribute to growth in labour productivity is examined in this article for manufacturing and services industries in eight major EU countries. We test the relevance of two engines of growth, i.e., the strategies of technological competitiveness (based on innovation in products and markets) and cost competitiveness (relying on innovation in processes and machinery) and their impact on economic performance. We propose models for the determinants of changes in labour productivity and we carry out empirical tests for both the whole economy and for the four Revised Pavitt classes that group manufacturing and services industries with distinct patterns of innovation. Tests are carried out by pooling industries, countries and three time periods, using innovation survey data from CIS 2, 3 and 4, linked to economic variables. The results confirm the specificity of the two engines of growth ; economic performances in European industries appear as the result of different innovation models, with strong specificities of the four Revised Pavitt classes. 2010 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. 1. Introduction 1 The relationship between innovation and productivity growth is at the centre of continuing interest in academic and policy-oriented research. In this article we propose improvements in the existing literature in three directions: we identify two different innovation strategies with specific effects on labour productivity; we show that these Corresponding author at: Viale delle Provincie 184, 00162 Roma, Italy. Tel.: +39 333 3396528; fax: +39 06 8841859. E-mail address: mario.pianta@uniurb.it (M. Pianta). 1 This paper is based on the Report for the IPTS project The impact of R&D and innovation on economic performance and employment: a quantitative analysis based on innovation survey data (J03/32/2007) by Mario Pianta and Francesco Bogliacino. We thank Marco Vivarelli for his advice and collaboration, Alfred Kleinknecht, Rinaldo Evangelista, Xabier Goenaga, Hector Hernandez, Raquel Ortega-Argilés and two referees for their comments. All remaining errors are responsibility of the authors. two engines of growth operate differently in the industry groups identified by a revised Pavitt taxonomy of industries; we test these patterns using an original database linking innovation survey and economic performance data for manufacturing and service industries. First, following a Schumpeterian insight, we move beyond the notion of an undifferentiated technological change (usually proxied by R&D or patents) that leads to productivity improvements, and we explore the existence of two distinct engines of labour productivity growth the search for technological competitiveness, with efforts to improve performance through new products and new markets, and the strategy of cost competitiveness, based on process innovation and labour saving technological change (Pianta, 2001). The former relies on product innovation, requires substantial internal innovative efforts, reflected by formal R&D, patenting and design activities, with the objective to enlarge product range and opening up new markets. The latter, rooted in process innovation, aims at increasing 0954-349X/$ see front matter 2010 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. doi:10.1016/j.strueco.2010.11.002

42 F. Bogliacino, M. Pianta / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 22 (2011) 41 53 efficiency through labour saving investment, restructuring and flexibilization of production, and cut-price competition. These strategies are conceptually different and respond to specific objectives of firms. In the practice of innovation in firms, these strategies coexist and are complementary; the evidence of innovation surveys shows that most firms that introduce new products also innovate in processes (Eurostat, 2008), and several studies have identified the close links between these two activities (Evangelista, 1999; Reichstein and Salter, 2006). However, at the industry level, the differences in technological regimes (Breschi et al., 2000) and the constraint posed by demand dynamics lead to a relative prevalence of one of the two strategies, shaping the trajectory of technological change. Such patterns affect economic performance, employment and distribution, as documented by a large body of research (Bogliacino and Pianta, 2008, 2010; Crespi and Pianta, 2008a,b; Pianta and Tancioni, 2008). A similar evidence has emerged from studies on the nature and impact of product and process innovation (Scherer, 1991; Cohen and Klepper, 1994; Edquist et al., 2001). Moreover, we combine a focus on innovation on the supply side with consideration of the dynamics of demand and its Kaldorian effect on productivity growth. In the model and in the results of Sections 3 and 4, we show that the strategies of technological and cost competitiveness affect industries productivity growth in fundamentally different ways, while demand plays a consistently positive role. A second distinction that we introduce is that between groups of industries in both manufacturing and services characterised by different patterns of technological change and innovation performance relationships. A large literature has shown that the patterns and effects of technological change depend on industries technological regimes, where the knowledge base, the appropriability conditions and the degree of cumulativeness define specific trajectories (Dosi, 1988; Breschi et al., 2000). Industry taxonomies such as the one proposed by Pavitt (1984) have been helpful in operationalising such an approach, but have generally been confined to manufacturing industry alone. We rely on the revised Pavitt taxonomy that we extended to service industries in Bogliacino and Pianta (2008, 2010) and test our models separately on the four revised Pavitt classes. Our results show that the two engines of productivity growth operate in different ways in each technological regime. The third novelty of this article lies in its empirical evidence, based on three waves of the Community Innovation Survey (CIS, see Eurostat, 2008), linked to data on industries economic performance. The rich information offered by innovation surveys on the types of innovations, their inputs, outputs, objectives and sources makes it possible to identify the diversity of patterns of technological change, providing a strong empirical base for the conceptual distinction between strategies of technological and cost competitiveness. At the industry level, CIS data are able to characterise the heterogeneity of technological activities and to provide a consistent picture of the patterns over time (from the mid 1990s to 2004), across industries covering services as well as manufacturing and countries (Bogliacino and Pianta, 2008). The systematic use of such data is a major novelty with respect to the literature based on R&D and patents, which are poor proxies of the technological activity carried out in firms outside science based sectors. By using innovation survey data, matched at the industry level with information on economic performance (from OECD STAN) and education (from Labour Force Surveys), we can move beyond the standard productivity analysis, based on measures of (undifferentiated) inputs of capital and labour. By combining these three novelties in the study of innovation and productivity, we improve on models where a single indicator accounts for the complex nature of technological change and is assumed to have the same effects across all industries. Our results identify the specific relationships linking different innovation strategies to labour productivity growth, in industry groups marked by distinct technological regimes. The paper proceeds as follows: Section 2 presents a review of the literature, Section 3 discusses models, data and methodology, in Section 4 we show the results, Section 5 concludes. 2. The relevant literature This article is related to four strands of research. First we analyze the role of R&D as part of the set of innovative options available to individual firms in explaining productivity growth. The related stream of literature started with Griliches (1979, 1995, 2000) and is rich of contributions at the national, sectoral and firm levels, finding evidence of a positive and significant impact of R&D on productivity, with some variability in terms of magnitude. 2 Firm level studies include Griliches and Mairesse (1982) on US and French data, and Cuneo and Mairesse (1983) on French firms; they distinguish between firms belonging to science-related sectors and other firms, and find a substantial impact of R&D on productivity in the former (elasticity equal to 0.20), twice as large as in the rest of firms. Ortega-Argiles et al. (2009) studied the top 532 European R&D investors, finding that the R&D coefficient shows higher values and significance as move from low-tech to medium-tech and high-tech industries. 3 Industry level studies have shown weaker evidence of the R&D-productivity link. Verspagen (1995) used a R&Daugmented production function and found that in OECD countries the effect of R&D on output was positive and significant in high-tech sectors only, with no impact in 2 In this approach, productivity has been calculated either as value added per worker (or per hour) or as TFP (among recent studies, see Klette and Kortum, 2004; Janz et al., 2004; Rogers, 2006; Lööf and Heshmati, 2006). The estimated average elasticity of productivity with respect to R&D ranges from 0.05 to 0.25 (see Mairesse and Sassenou, 1991 for a survey; Griliches, 1995, 2000; Mairesse and Mohnen, 2001). 3 Other studies in a large literature include Wakelin (2001), who examined the impact of R&D, capital and labour on productivity in 170 UK quoted firms in the years 1988 1992, finding a positive and significant role of R&D. Tsai and Wang (2004) investigated 156 large Taiwanese quoted firms over 1994 2000, reporting a positive and significant R&D effect on productivity (elasticity equal to 0.18); in high-tech firms the impact was much higher than in low-tech ones (0.3 against 0.07).

F. Bogliacino, M. Pianta / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 22 (2011) 41 53 43 medium and low-tech sectors. An overview and critical evaluation of this literature can be found in Hall et al. (2010). In this article we carry out analyses at the industry level, finding estimated coefficients that are in line with the existing literature, and showing that R&D is not equally important in all industries. A major strength of our investigation is the rich characterisation of innovative efforts, made possible by the use of data from Community Innovation Surveys. We share this approach with a second strand of literature which had used the evidence from innovation surveys 4 in order to investigate the determinants of innovation 5 and to explore the relationships between R&D, innovation and productivity. Crépon et al. (1998) have developed a widely tested model where R&D affects innovation, which in turn affects productivity (see also Mohnen and Röller, 2005). A systematic application of such a model at the firm level to major OECD countries has been recently carried out, finding that firms that are large, part of a group and active in foreign markets are those more likely to report innovative efforts, such as R&D expenditures. Such activities lead to increasing sales from new products and, in turn, this is associated to higher productivity levels (measured by log sales per employee) (OECD, 2009). While the stability of results across several countries confirms the strength of such relationships, innovative efforts are conceptualized as a homogeneous activity, and no distinction between different strategies is made. In a similar framework, Crespi et al. (2008) used CIS data to build a panel of UK firms and explore the learningby-exporting hypothesis; they test the effect of export on learning considering clients as a source of knowledge and of learning on performance, finding that firms who export show an advantage in (labour) productivity. Our approach is somehow complementary; although we cannot control for export, we allow the source of learning to change across industries and we found that the client channel is particularly relevant for suppliers dominated industries. Building on the strength of CIS data, we are able to take into account the heterogeneity of innovative efforts with a coverage of several countries, successive CIS waves and links to other data sources improving on previous analyses that have used CIS data in a narrower context. 4 The availability of such data has made it possible to move beyond the reliance on R&D and patent data as the main indicators of technological activities. See Smith (2005) for a discussion on the measurement of innovation. R&D data underestimate research in service industries and do not account for innovative activities linked to design, engineering and new processes. Patents are a rough proxy of innovation as not all inventions are patented; inventions may have widely differing economic relevance; patenting is biased towards large firms; different sectors show very different propensities to patent their inventions; patenting is negligible or not available for the innovations of most service industries (Archibugi and Pianta, 1996). 5 For reviews, see Baldwin and Hanel (2003), Kleinknecht and Mohnen (2002), Van Beers et al. (2008), and Mairesse and Mohnen (2010). Additional questions addressed by this literature include the innovation performance link in services (Crespi et al., 2006; Evangelista, 2000; Evangelista and Savona, 2003); the analysis of complementarities among innovation strategies (Catozzella and Vivarelli, 2007). The Schumpeterian distinction between product and process innovation is the starting point of the third stream of studies that explored the empirical evidence on their differences and relationships with market structure and productivity. Since the work by Cohen and Levin (1989), the robustness of such a distinction has been documented with a variety of approaches (Link, 1982; Scherer, 1991; Cohen and Klepper, 1994; Edquist et al., 2001), while other studies have pointed out the close links existing in the development of new products and new processes (Pisano, 1997; Reichstein and Salter, 2006). More recently, the use of innovation surveys has made it possible a systematic investigation of the different effects that new products and new processes in the context of the strategies of technological and cost competitiveness have on productivity and performance at the industry level (Pianta, 2001; Crespi and Pianta, 2008a,b,c). Parallel studies at the firm level have confirmed the different impacts of innovation in products, processes and organisations (Parisi et al., 2006; Evangelista and Vezzani, 2010). However, while new products and new processes reflect different directions of technological change, they should not be seen as alternative to one another; rather they can be complementary efforts in the search for productivity increases, and combine in different ways in particular industry groups. 6 The fourth line of research has addressed the challenge of identifying such industry groups, characterised by a different nature of innovation and a different pace of productivity growth. The evolution of industries is shaped by technological trajectories and regimes, and is affected by sectoral systems of innovation, where different opportunities, selection processes, and performances are found (Winter, 1984; Dosi, 1988; Breschi et al., 2000; Malerba, 2004). The Pavitt taxonomy developed on the SPRU database on innovation in UK manufacturing firms (Pavitt, 1984) represents a major effort to conceptualize these differences and has been widely adopted in studies on firms and industries. 7 A revised Pavitt taxonomy, extended to services and addressing the role of ICT industries, has been developed by Bogliacino and Pianta (2008), where a detailed discussion and statistical tests are provided. In this article we adopt such a revised taxonomy in order to highlight the diversity in the relationships between innovation and productivity. An application of the revised Pavitt taxonomy to investigate the innovation employment link is in Bogliacino and Pianta (2010). In this article we combine such different streams of literature with an empirical analysis at the industry level 6 In a pioneering study using innovation survey data, Evangelista (1999) showed that in science based industries a strong relevance of R&D efforts and new products is combined with a strong innovation in the processes required for their production. 7 For a review and a discussion, see Archibugi (2001). Pavitt et al. (1989) applied the taxonomy to the case of UK firms; Dosi et al. (1990) and Guerrieri (1999) have used Pavitt classes to investigate the link between technology and international trade; Dosi et al. (2008) analysed the firm size distribution; Marsili and Verspagen (2002) analysed Dutch firms; Evangelista (2000) and Evangelista and Savona (2003) investigated Italian microdata; Castellacci (2008) applied it to 24 European countries.

44 F. Bogliacino, M. Pianta / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 22 (2011) 41 53 on manufacturing and services. Moving beyond the notion of an undifferentiated technological change, we model and test the role of two distinct engines of productivity growth the strategies of technological and cost competitiveness. We also explore their impact in industry groups characterised by a different nature of technological change, finding important differences in the sources of productivity growth. 3. Models, data and methodology We use a database recently developed at the University of Urbino the Sectoral Innovation Database (SID). Such database includes most variables of three comparable waves of the Community Innovation Survey (CIS 2, 3 and 4), and integrates innovation data with a large amount of statistical information on economic performance and employment at the same sectoral level, drawn from different sources (mainly OECD STAN). The country coverage of the database includes 8 major European countries Germany, France, Italy, Norway, Netherlands, Portugal, Spain, and United Kingdom that represent more than eighty percent of the European Economy. Data are available for the two-digit NACE classification of both manufacturing and service industries. The full description of the sources and methodology followed for the construction of the database is provided in the SID Methodological Notes (University of Urbino, 2007). Table A1 in the Appendix A shows the industries included into the SID, grouped in the four Revised Pavitt classes. The matching between STAN data and CIS data takes into account the need to let technology display its effect with a lag, and the time span for which data are available. CIS data refers to 1994 1996 (CIS 2), 1998 2000 (CIS 3), and 2002 2004 (CIS 4) and, considering data availability, for variables on economic performance we have used the changes over the periods 1996 1999 for CIS 2, 2000 2003 for CIS 3, and 2003 2006 for CIS 4. We start from a general model common to all industries, and move towards more specific versions, including variables that reflect in a more appropriate way the particular technological activities typical of each Revised Pavitt class, so that we can better capture the complex relationships between innovation and economic performance across European industries. As a microfoundation, we can propose the following model: y ijt = tc ijtˇ1 + cc ijtˇ2 + d ijtˇ3 + u ij + v ijt where all variables are assumed to be measured in log scale; y is the productivity level, by tc we want to identify a technology based on competences and capabilities for the development of new products, i.e., belonging to the technological competitiveness trajectory; similarly, by cc we identify a technology based on competences and capabilities over production processes, where cost concerns are important and that belongs to a cost competitiveness trajectory. We add also a demand variable d, allowing the system to have a Kaldorian mechanism of dynamic increasing returns. The error components term has standard properties. We remind that i identifies industry, j country and t time. By taking the difference, we get the following equation: y ijt = tc ijtˇ1 + cc ijtˇ2 + d ijtˇ3 + v ijt where the variations in the technologies adopted are reflected by the different types of innovative activities carried out over time. While tc and cc define the technology that exists at one point in time in firms, which affects labour productivity (in level), its variation can be proxied by the set of variables in terms of innovative activities, expenditures and performances that are referred to a given period. Such activities lead to an evolution of the stock of technology and describe how firms are changing products and processes; even when they are described as intensities (or percentages of total firms, rather than in terms of rate of change), they are proxies for the flow of new technological activities that adds on the existing stock of technological capabilities, both product and process-oriented. We adjust for heteroschedasticity and we adjust also for intra-group correlation at industry level (for the presence of intra-industry heterogeneity). We maintain a constant, for the presence of an eventual trend in productivity. The industry data we use are grouped data of unequal size, and in some cases we have sectors with very small size and modest economic relevance; their contribution in terms of information cannot be expected to be equal and this affects the consistency of the estimation. A way to guarantee consistency is the use of weighted least squares that allows to take the relevance of industries into account (see the discussion in Wooldridge, 2002, chap. 17). Since consistency relies on correct observability of the weight, we use the number of employees as the weighting factor. The latter is the standard weighting variable used by statistical offices and is not affected by prices, as is the case with value added, the typical alternative weighting factor. With regards to potential endogeneity of the innovation indicators, we use predetermined variables: since our time lags are of three to four year long, the autoregressive character (and the implied endogeneity) is considerably softened. The use of long differences as a means to deal with endogeneity problems is well known in the literature, e.g., Caroli and Van Reenen (2001) and Piva et al. (2005). Moreover, the differencing eliminates the individual effect. In a first step we apply a general model to all industries. The dependent variable is the average annual compound rate of change of value added per employee. Among the large number of innovation variables in our database, we selected the regressors following two main criteria: their closeness to theory and their economic and statistical robustness. Closeness to theory leads to consider variables capable to account for different innovative activities (such as R&D or the acquisition of machinery) and strategies (such as the search for new markets or for labour cost reduction), capable to capture the economic relevance of new products (share of innovative turnover), or capable to document specific innovative behaviours (e.g., we used the share of firms identifying clients as a source of innovation because neo-schumpeterian theory stresses the importance of this relation for several industries).

F. Bogliacino, M. Pianta / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 22 (2011) 41 53 45 Table 1 The determinants of labour productivity growth. 1 2 3 WLS rob s.e. WLS rob s.e. WLS rob s.e. In-house R&D expenditure per employee 0.147 (0.044) *** 0.163 (0.046) *** 0.170 (0.035) *** Machinery expenditure 0.168 (0.073) ** 0.132 (0.097) Share of firms with suppliers of equipment as sources of innovation 0.050 (0.013) *** Secondary education (share) 0.063 (0.011) *** 0.049 (0.011) *** Rate of growth of value added 0.702 (0.052) *** 0.678 (0.068) *** 0.666 (0.063) *** Constant 0.205(0.268) 3.402 (0.611) *** 3.575 (0.618) *** N obs 618 284 307 R 2 0.48 0.51 0.54 *Significant at the 90% level. Economic and statistical robustness leads us to consider variables that provide general measures (such as expenditure on machinery or in house R&D) and a large coverage of countries and industries. After this general model we will run separate regressions for each revised Pavitt class in order to identify specific channels of productivity growth related to different technological regimes. The revised Pavitt taxonomy that includes service industries is presented in Table A1 in the Appendix A and relies on extensive work for identifying key differences in innovation patterns at the sectoral level (Bogliacino and Pianta, 2008). The rich information provided by innovation surveys has allowed us to investigate the determinants of innovation, the inputs and sources of knowledge used, the objectives that were pursued and the resulting economic impact. We close this section with a summary of the variables used in the analysis. The dependent variable labour productivity is expressed by value added per employee. Innovation variables (all from CIS sources) can be divided in two groups, those representing technological competitiveness and those related to cost competitiveness. Among the technological competitiveness variables we use: In house R&D per employee Share of firms which applied for a patent Share of firms which aim to open up a new market. Among the cost competitiveness variables we use: Expenditure (per employee) in new machinery and equipment; Share of firms who indicate suppliers as source of knowledge (and share of firms who indicate clients, only for Suppliers Dominated industries); Share of firms which innovate to flexibilize production processes; Share of firms innovating with the aim to reduce labour costs; Share of firms which innovate buying new machinery and equipment. As a proxy of demand we use industry value added for two reasons: (a) value added is equal to the sum of all demand components directed to each industry, and is readily available for the relevant time periods; (b) in several studies we have shown that value added is a good predictor of the role played by consumption, investment and exports the main sources of final demand that we calculated using input-output tables for selected years (Crespi and Pianta, 2008a,b,c). As a proxy for human capital we use the share of employee with secondary education taken from Labour Force Survey (mainly for data availability). 4. Results In Table 1 we present the results for the baseline regression. In this general model, across all manufacturing and service industries, labour productivity growth appears to be supported by both strategies of technological and cost competitiveness proxied by R&D and machinery expenditure and by demand growth, proxied by the change in industries value added, that accounts for the Kaldorian role of increasing returns. All variables are positive and significant. If we look at the order of magnitude of the coefficients, we may see that cost competitiveness and technological competitiveness appear equally important to explain the overall performance. For the latter variable we can see that the coefficient belongs to the interval of previous estimates of the impact of R&D on productivity (namely, 0.05 0.25, see footnote 2). impact is less than half of that value, but it is difficult to make comparisons given the different scales of the variables. The successful introduction of technological change, requires the presence of appropriate competences and skills in the labour force; such information is not provided by innovation surveys, but we could draw from Labour

46 F. Bogliacino, M. Pianta / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 22 (2011) 41 53 force surveys data on the share of workers with secondary education in 2000 and 2003 for the five largest countries (the Netherlands, Norway and Portugal are not included), which can be related to the innovation data of CIS 3 and CIS4. In spite of the loss in the number of cases, this variable introduces an important additional dimension, with a proxy of workers competences in industries. The results of the baseline model with human capital are shown in column 2. There is an improvement in the fitness, and the quality of labour has a significantly positive effect on productivity, but the introduction of the further regressors affects the significance of the machinery variable. For these reason, we substitute it with a source variable: the share of firms that identify the suppliers of machinery and equipment as the main origin of their innovation. The results are in column 3 of Table 1. This regression identifies the key sources of labour productivity growth, the innovation-based strategies of technological and cost competitiveness, the average skill of labour, and the Kaldorian role of demand growth accounting for increasing returns. Additional versions of this simple model have been tested. In the Appendix A we provide the tables with additional results and a discussion of technical issues. We start by looking at separate regressions on manufacturing and services: the results are confirmed, with the exception of the cost competitiveness variable for manufacturing. We move forward to consider three separate issues: the potential existence of catching up in productivity levels, the robustness of the results to the potential objection of endogeneity for the Kaldor Verdoorn effect; finally the role of wages. First, the relevance of catching up in productivity was tested. The issue is important at the micro level, where imitation may lead to convergence in productivity among competing firms, and has been widely addressed also in the context of the growth performances of countries. At the industry level, there is little ground for assuming a process of convergence among sectors within the same country; in fact the idea of inter-sectoral convergence seems at odds with the theory and evidence on structural change. We considered the possibility of an inter-country convergence in the same industries, e.g., the hypothesis that labour productivity in Portuguese industries may tend to converge to the productivity level of the same industries in Germany. Such national patterns could be captured in a rough way by country dummies, but the results do not add much to the results we obtained above. 8 In a more specific test, we included in the model a measure of the relative distance of industries productivity levels from the top European performer; the results were never significant, in any of the specifications we tested (see the Appendix A). In fact, we may argue that our model explicitly considers the different sources of technological change based on either new products or new processes, on the introduction of major novelties as well as on imitation and diffusion of small innovations and directly accounts for the mechanisms that have sometimes been indirectly captured by prox- 8 In fact, since the underlying model is based on a difference transformation to obtain the rate of change, country dummies are eliminated. ies of catching up effects in labour productivity in studies that could not include innovation variables in their models. This result may be important under a policy perspective: the lack of a catching up process in productivity means that convergence is no longer a driver of growth within Europe. Second, the strength of change in value added as a proxy of demand and its independence from productivity growth has been considered, testing for endogeneity. There is a large literature on the role of demand in innovation and productivity growth, and on the Kaldor Verdoorn effect (see Crespi and Pianta, 2008a,b for a discussion and references). Endogeneity may exists whenever the increase of productivity expand the growth of that sector. We instrumented the value added variable using the growth of operating surplus, that is certainly correlated with the rate of change of value added, but is determined by the distributive conflict. We show with a TSLS (Two Stages Least Squares) regression that our regression is robust (see the Appendix A). Third, the possibility of a wage-productivity relation, through an efficiency wage effect, has been considered. If we include wage growth in our model we find significant results, but it seems very difficult to distinguish the chain of causation, and the standard relationship from productivity growth to wage increases (rather than vice versa) remains the most convincing one (see the Appendix A). 4.1. The results on revised Pavitt classes Aggregate evidence on the relationship between productivity and innovation in the Pavitt groupings can be found in Fig. 1. Fig. 1 suggests that our conceptualization is grounded into empirical evidence. Science Based industries concentrate on R&D (and use new machinery as well), and have the highest rates of productivity growth, more than three times higher than the Suppliers Dominated and Specialised Suppliers groups. The intermediate productivity performance of the Scale and Information Intensive industries heavily relies on process innovation. For the Suppliers Dominated group the low economic performance appears rooted in the low levels of innovative activities, while Specialised Suppliers rely more on research as well as on the continuing high employment of (relatively skilled) labour as we will see below and this may explain the low productivity increases found here. The results of the econometric test of the basic model for the four Revised Pavitt classes are shown in Table 2. The basic model appears less appropriate to account for the specificities of the four Revised Pavitt classes. Technological competitiveness emerges for Science Based, Specialised Suppliers and Suppliers Dominated, while the search for cost competitiveness through new machinery does not emerge in any class. The significant coefficient of R&D for Suppliers Dominated captures the activity of firms who develop new products in traditional sectors, but the evidence of Fig. 1 reminds us of the limited extent of R&D efforts in this industry group. growth is always significant, with the highest coefficient for SII sectors and the lowest for SD, confirming

F. Bogliacino, M. Pianta / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 22 (2011) 41 53 47 Fig. 1. Competitiveness strategies and productivity growth. the stylized fact that scale factors are crucial in the former and least relevant in the latter. Major missing factors can be identified: the importance of scale economies for Scale and Information Intensive industries is not captured by the machinery expenditure; the role of customers in driving the innovative process for in Specialised Suppliers industries is not emerging. These results suggest that there is large room for improving the explanatory ability of the model by searching for more specific versions that can account for the specificity of the innovation productivity relationship in each of the four groups. We therefore develop specific versions of the productivity equation for each Revised Pavitt class, introducing specific relevant variables. Table 3 reports the estimates for Science Based industries. As widely documented, R&D is the main determinant of the innovative activity in this group. In house research and external acquisition are both significant. Although machinery is not significant, there is a relevant role of the suppliers of equipment that contribute to productivity growth through improved processes. The share of workers with secondary education is not significant, but it can be a poor proxy of the human capital employed here. is positive and significant, as expected. As a further robustness check, in column (4) we substitute R&D for a good proxy for product innovation, the share of firms applying for a patent, that is positive and significant, as expected. The sources of productivity growth in this group appear to Table 2 The determinants of labour productivity growth in the Revised Pavitt classes. 1 2 3 4 SB SII SS SD WLS rob s.e. WLS rob s.e. WLS rob s.e. WLS rob s.e. In-house R&D expenditure per employee 0.103 (0.064) * 0.081 (0.091) 0.291 (0.113) ** 0.394 (0.161) * Machinery expenditure 0.092 (0.121) 0.087 (0.105) 0.280 (0.198) 0.143 (0.163) Rate of growth of value added 0.762 (0.140) *** 0.836 (0.067) *** 0.775 (0.088) *** 0.466 (0.091) *** Constant 0.632 (0.838) 0.863 (0.419) ** 1.589 (0.651) ** 0.051 (0.370) N obs 111 184 92 231 R 2 0.54 0.74 0.57 0.19 * Significant at the 90% level.

48 F. Bogliacino, M. Pianta / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 22 (2011) 41 53 Table 3 The determinants of labour productivity growth in Science Based Industries. 1 2 3 4 WLS rob s.e. WLS rob s.e. WLS rob s.e. WLS rob s.e. In-house R&D expenditure per employee 0.103 (0.064) * 0.104 (0.042) ** 0.135 (0.050) ** Patent application (share of firms) 0.044 (0.027) * Machinery expenditure 0.092 (0.121) 0.112 (0.100) Share of firms with suppliers of equipment as sources of innovation 0.044 (0.019) ** 0.055 (0.026) ** Share of workers with secondary education 0.024 (0.031) Rate of growth of value added 0.762 (0.140) *** 0.811 (0.134) *** 0.802 (0.163) *** 0.755 (0.138) *** Constant 0.632 (0.838) -0.602 (0.840) -2.106 (1.570) 0.420 (0.832) N obs 111 110 60 109 R 2 0.54 0.60 0.56 0.58 * Significant at the 90% level. be well identified by this model, and are consistent with the theory and previous findings for R&D intensive industries. We now move to the case of Scale and Information Intensive industries (Table 4). In this group we do not find robust evidence on product innovation: R&D is not significantly affecting productivity growth, while an important influence is played by the share of firms indicating the suppliers of equipment as the source of their (process) innovation. The share of workers with secondary education has a significantly positive role, while the search for new markets plays no (or negative) effect. As expected, demand growth is important. The Specialised Suppliers group is made up by industries where there is a non-negligible R&D, highly skilled labour, flexible small scale production arrangements and a strong relation with customers, all elements that drive the innovative process. The results, in Table 5, confirm our expectations; in-house R&D expenditure is significant and positive, clients are important sources of innovation and both the strategies of labour saving and increasing flexibility are positively related with productivity growth. The share of employees with secondary education is not significant, although positive, as the skills that are relevant for the industries are not easily reflected by the educational level. has a strong effect, as usual. We now move to the last group, Suppliers Dominated industries, where R&D is confined to a small share of firms and new processes dominate the innovative strategy. The results are in Table 6. All coefficients come out as expected, apart from machinery expenditure, which loses significance. The role of clients in driving technological change is similar to the result found for Specialised Suppliers and points out the relevance of user-driven innovation (users in this case can also be final consumers). The human capital variable is positive and significant and demand dynamics strongly contributes to productivity growth. Three main findings emerge from Tables 3 6. First, innovative efforts for technological and cost competitiveness are main drivers of productivity growth. Second, demand Table 4 The determinants of labour productivity growth in Scale and Information Intensive industries. 1 2 3 WLS rob s.e. WLS rob s.e. WLS rob s.e. In-house R&D expenditure per employee 0.081 (0.091) Share of firms aiming to open up new markets 0.023 (0.018) 0.044 (0.019) ** Machinery expenditure 0.087 (0.105) Share of firms buying machinery 0.043 (0.019) ** Share of firms with suppliers of equipment as sources of innovation 0.054 (0.019) *** Share of workers with secondary education 0.053 (0.016) *** Rate of growth of value added 0.836 (0.067) *** 0.881 (0.054) *** 0.829 (0.067) *** Constant 0.863 (0.419) ** 0.261 (0.685) 1.928 (0.913) ** N obs 184 196 79 R 2 0.74 0.79 0.86 *Significant at the 90% level.

F. Bogliacino, M. Pianta / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 22 (2011) 41 53 49 Table 5 The determinants of labour productivity growth in Specialised Suppliers Industries. 1 2 3 4 WLS rob s.e. WLS rob s.e. WLS rob s.e. WLS rob s.e. In-house R&D expenditure 0.277 (0.099) *** 0.238 (0.080) *** 0.219 (0.104) ** 0.267 (0.090) *** Share aiming to reduce labour cost 0.040 (0.017) ** Share of firms aiming to more flexible production process 0.056 (0.021) *** Share of firms with clients as sources of innovation 0.048 (0.016) *** 0.058 (0.031) * Share of workers with secondary education 0.038 (0.046) Rate of growth of value added 0.766 (0.070) *** 0.744 (0.072) *** 0.780 (0.103) *** 0.742 (0.074) *** Constant 2.091 (0.685) *** 2.586 (0.704) *** 4.699 (1.511) *** 2.458 (0.745) *** N obs 89 90 50 89 R 2 0.62 0.66 0.67 0.63 * Significant at the 90% level. Table 6 The determinants of labour productivity growth in Suppliers Dominated Industries. 1 2 3 WLS rob s.e. WLS rob s.e. WLS rob s.e. Share of firms aiming to more flexible production process 0.041 (0.014) *** 0.052 (0.021) ** Machinery expenditure per employee 0.009(0.147) 0.006 (0.149) 0.001 (0.194) Share of firms with clients as sources of innovation 0.043 (0.012) *** Share of workers with secondary education 0.054 (0.012) *** Rate of growth of value added 0.451 (0.087) *** 0.432 (0.086) *** 0.341 (0.110) *** Constant 0.510 (0.445) 0.596 (0.422) 3.379 (0.751) *** N obs 225 226 112 R 2 0.22 0.23 0.32 *Significant at the 90% level. growth always contributes to greater productivity. Third, the use of a single general model for explaining productivity improvements fails to capture the diversity in the engines of growth in distinct industry groups characterised by differences in the nature of the innovation process and in technology regimes. 5. Conclusions In this article we have shown that the mechanisms at the root of technological change and the engines of labour productivity growth are related to the different strategies pursuing either technological competitiveness (such as innovation in products and markets) or cost competitiveness (such as innovation in processes and machinery, see Pianta, 2001). An understanding of economic performance in Europe in the last two decades requires an appropriate use of the previous results in order to explain the different patterns of productivity growth across countries and industries. Both technological and cost competitiveness strategies have contributed to better economic performance, operating through radically different mechanisms. However, only Science Based industries, that have heavily invested in both, can show rapid productivity increases. Moreover, a parallel expansion of demand and an adequate qualification of workers represent additional key factors for explaining labour productivity performances across all industries in Europe. In fact, the operation of the two engines of productivity growth differs significantly across manufacturing and service industries; we have shown that Revised Pavitt groups are able to effectively summarise this diversity. Science Based industries show that better economic performances are obtained through the search for greater technological competitiveness that is effectively described by variables such as R&D efforts and patent application. A significant role is played by efforts for cost competitiveness, proxied by the share of firms indicating the suppliers of equipment as the source of (process) innovation; here we can expect user-producer interactions to be relevant. growth is always highly important, showing the relevance of increasing returns in this sector. Scale and Information Intensive industries mainly rely on a cost competitiveness strategy with a major role played by the share of firms indicating the suppliers of equipment

50 F. Bogliacino, M. Pianta / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 22 (2011) 41 53 as the source of their (process) innovation. The mid-level skills of workers with secondary education are significant sources of better performances, while the search for new markets plays no (or negative) effect. growth is important, suggesting the relevance of new expanding service markets. Specialised Suppliers industries appear to rely on a more complex set of sources for productivity growth. Technological competitiveness plays a clear role proxied by R&D expenditures but costs competitiveness factors are also present share of firms aiming at lower labour costs or more flexible processes and we can identify the highly specific role of interaction with clients among the sources of success in this group. While secondary education is not significant, demand growth is highly important. Suppliers Dominated industries are characterised by the model of cost competitiveness, with the search for more flexible production and a role of clients as sources of innovation. The mid-level skills of workers with secondary education are significant, and also demand growth plays a role, although with coefficients much lower than in previous models. This empirical and econometric analysis of the relationship between innovation and economic performances appears robust in different versions of the model (see the additional tests carried out in the Appendix A) and confirms the strength of the Revised Pavitt taxonomy as a way to identify the diversity of innovation across industries and the specificity of the sources of productivity growth. The tests developed in this paper (and the additional ones carried out in the Appendix A) provide a solid evidence of systematic differences in the models explaining productivity growth across Revised Pavitt classes. A number of policy lessons emerge from our findings. Policies aiming at greater labour productivity growth may have to take into account the different mechanisms resulting from technological and cost competitiveness strategies, and the different relevance that they have in industry groups. Efforts to introduce new processes have emerged as a strong aspect of innovative activities in all industries, but their impact on productivity growth is likely to be inferior to that of a search for new products and markets, typical of Science Based and Specialised Suppliers industries alone. Policies may therefore be more effective when they focus on the latter type of efforts. As the dynamics of demand plays a strong role in the potential for productivity growth, innovation policies could also develop a stronger integration with industrial and macroeconomic policies. Appendix A. See Table A1. A.1. The basic productivity equation: a discussion A first point to address is the stability of the pooling between manufacturing and services, coherently with the conclusion of the Schumpeterian literature quoted in Section 2.In Table A2 we run separately the baseline regression on restricted samples of manufacturing and services industries only. Table A1 Industries included in the SID (with NACE code) and the Revised Pavitt taxonomy. Revised Pavitt taxonomy NACE Science based Chemicals 24 Office machinery 30 Manufacture of radio, television and 32 communication equipment and apparatus Manufacture of medical, precision and 33 optical instruments, watches and clocks Communications 64 Computer and related activities 72 Research and development 73 Scale and information intensive Pulp, paper and paper products 29 Printing and publishing 31 Mineral oil refining, coke and nuclear fuel 35 Rubber and plastics 70 Non-metallic mineral products 71 Basic metals 74 Motor vehicles Financial intermediation, except insurance and pension funding Insurance and pension funding, except 21 compulsory social security Activities auxiliary to financial 22 intermediation 23 Specialised suppliers 25 Mechanical engineering 26 Manufacture of electrical machinery and 27 apparatus n.e.c. Manufacture of other transport equipment 34 Real estate activities 65 Renting of machinery and equipment 66 Other business activities 67 Suppliers dominated Food, drink and tobacco 15 16 Textiles 17 Clothing 18 Leather and footwear 19 Wood and products of wood and cork 20 Fabricated metal products 28 Furniture, miscellaneous manufacturing; 36 37 recycling Sale, maintenance and repair of motor 50 vehicles and motorcycles; retail sale of automotive fuel Wholesale trade and commission trade, 51 except of motor vehicles and motorcycles Retail trade, except of motor vehicles and 52 motorcycles; repair of personal and household goods Hotels and catering 55 Inland transport 60 Water transport 61 Air transport 62 Supporting and auxiliary transport activities; 63 activities of travel agencies There are only minor differences: a lack of significance in machinery for manufacturing, and a much higher demand coefficient for services, reflecting the greater expansion of new service markets. Moving to more theoretical concerns, we start by discussing the possibility of a catching up effect in productivity. The point is not straightforward: while at the firm level we can think of imitation effects, and at the country level some convergence process may take place, at the