JUSTIFICATION AND CRITIQUE OF THE PATENT SYSTEM DEAN CHEN PHIL 170, DUKE UNIVERSITY NOVEMBER 12 TH, 2011

Similar documents
Patents and Intellectual Property

The Economics of Patents Lecture 3

Economics of IPRs and patents

As a Patent and Trademark Resource Center (PTRC), the Pennsylvania State University Libraries has a mission to support both our students and the

Flexibilities in the Patent System

Patents & Innovation In the Pharmaceutical Industry: Literature Review. Jonathan Gock POL 459 Prof. Hira Fall 09

Getting Started. This Lecture

"Competition Policy and Intellectual Property Rights in the Republic of Latvia since 1991" (the working title)

Invention SUBMISSION BROCHURE PLEASE READ THE FOLLOWING BEFORE SUBMITTING YOUR INVENTION

Public Hearings Concerning the Evolving Intellectual Property Marketplace

Innovation and Intellectual Property Issues for Debate

Patents. What is a patent? What is the United States Patent and Trademark Office (USPTO)? What types of patents are available in the United States?

Topic 3 - Chapter II.B Primary consideration before drafting a patent application. Emmanuel E. Jelsch European Patent Attorney

An investment in a patent for your invention could be the best investment you will ever

TRIPS-Plus Provisions and Access to Technologies:

exceptional circumstance:

Issues and Possible Reforms in the U.S. Patent System

UNCTAD Ad Hoc Expert Meeting on the Green Economy: Trade and Sustainable Development Implications November

Draft for consideration

Patenting Strategies. The First Steps. Patenting Strategies / Bernhard Nussbaumer, 12/17/2009 1

INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY (IP) SME SCOREBOARD 2016

INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY (IP) SME SCOREBOARD 2016

WIPO REGIONAL SEMINAR ON SUPPORT SERVICES FOR INVENTORS, VALUATION AND COMMERCIALIZATION OF INVENTIONS AND RESEARCH RESULTS

What s in the Spec.?

PACKAGE LICENSES IN PATENT POOLS *

THE AMERICA INVENTS ACT NEW POST-ISSUANCE PATENT OFFICE PROCEEDINGS

IP For Entrepreneurs. For Background Education Only NOT LEGAL ADVICE

INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY AND ECONOMIC GROWTH

Intellectual Property Importance

Intellectual Property

International Intellectual Property Practices

Intellectual Property Overview

Patent Due Diligence

Technology Commercialization Primer: Understanding the Basics. Leza Besemann

Under the Patronage of His Highness Sayyid Faisal bin Ali Al Said Minister for National Heritage and Culture

Evaluating a Report of Invention & Licensing. Technology Development Boot Camp Peter Liao March 25, 2013

Slide 25 Advantages and disadvantages of patenting

PATENT PROTECTION FOR PHARMACEUTICAL PRODUCTS IN CANADA CHRONOLOGY OF SIGNIFICANT EVENTS

Basics of Intellectual Property for Business & Entrepreneurs

Statement of. Hon. General J. Mossinghoff Senior Counsel Oblon, Spivak, McClelland, Maier & Neustadt, P.C. before the

Questionnaire May Q178 Scope of Patent Protection. Answer of the French Group

U.S. Patent-Antitrust Interface. Alden F. Abbott, Heritage Foundation Oxford Competition Law Centre June 28, 2014

Intellectual Property Law Alert

Patent Basics for Inventors, Entrepreneurs, and Start-ups. Ned Landrum Patent Training Advisor STEPP Program Manager

Research Collection. Comment on Henkel, J. and F. Jell "Alternative motives to file for patents: profiting from pendency and publication.

Introduction to IP: Some Basics of Patents, Trademarks, & Trade Secrets

Intellectual Property

Patent Assertion Entity Activity: An FTC Study

Enforcement of Intellectual Property Rights Frequently Asked Questions

Intellectual Property

WIPO-IFIA INTERNATIONAL SYMPOSIUM ON THE COMMERCIALIZATION OF INVENTIONS IN THE GLOBAL MARKET

Outline 3/16/2018. Patent Basics for Inventors, Entrepreneurs, and Start-ups.

THE AMERICAN INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW ASSOCIATION RECOMMENDATIONS REGARDING QUALIFICATIONS FOR

Ways to Maximize Your Intellectual Property Assets

The 9 Sources of Innovation: Which to Use?

ACCOUNTING TREATMENT OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY

I. The First-to-File Patent System

CIEL Center for International Environmental Law

Intellectual Property

Intellectual Property Initiatives

Introduction to Intellectual Property

PROTECTING INVENTIONS: THE ROLE OF PATENTS, UTILITY MODELS AND DESIGNS

RANDI L. KARPINIA SENIOR PATENT OPERATIONS COUNSEL LAW DEPARTMENT, MOTOROLA SOLUTIONS INC.

Comments of the AMERICAN INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW ASSOCIATION. Regarding

Intellectual Property

Intellectual Property Rights and Development CARLOS M. CORREA

What is Intellectual Property?

Berkeley Postdoc Entrepreneur Program (BPEP)

Introduction to economic growth (4)

Global Trends in Patenting

11th Annual Patent Law Institute

Lewis-Clark State College No Date 2/87 Rev. Policy and Procedures Manual Page 1 of 7

7 The Trends of Applications for Industrial Property Rights in Japan

Patents and innovation (and competition) Bronwyn H. Hall UC Berkeley, U of Maastricht, NBER, and IFS London

STANDARDS SETTING, STANDARDS DEVELOPMENT AND DIVISION OF THE GAINS FROM STANDARDIZATION

Canada s Intellectual Property (IP) Strategy submission from Polytechnics Canada

If you can t do it better, why do it? -- Herbert H. Dow

Panel on IP Valuation: How Much is it Worth? How Much Can You Get? How Can You Protect It?

Clarity of thought: telling Congress how to improve 101

Patents and other Intellectual Property. Carl Otto Barth ABACUS Patentanwälte Klocke Späth Barth Adliswil/Zürich (CH) + Horb/Neckar (DE)

Bangkok, August 22 to 26, 2016 (face-to-face session) August 29 to October 30, 2016 (follow-up session) Claim Drafting Techniques

Software Patent Issues

PUBLISH AND YOUR PATENT RIGHTS MAY PERISH ALAN M. EHRLICH WEISS, MOY & HARRIS, P.C.

Patents: Who uses them, for what and what are they worth?

TESTIMONY OF DR. MARC J. OSTRO TO THE SUBCOMMITTEE ON PATENTS, COPYRIGHTS AND TRADEMARKS OCTOBER 23, 1985

CS 4984 Software Patents

Patents in an Environment of Global Collaboration

Key Strategies for Your IP Portfolio

WIPO NATIONAL WORKSHOP FOR PATENT LAWYERS

Patent Pools and Innovation: Evidence From Economic History

Why patents DO matter to YOUR business

FEATURES REAL-WORLD RESEARCH

Energy Trade and Transportation: Conscious Parallelism

Patent Law: What Anesthesiologists Should Know

Resilient Innovation for Economic Transformation

Why patents DO matter to YOUR business

INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW

Valerie S. Gaydos Angel Investor President, Capital Growth, Inc. How Proposed Patent Reform Increases Risk for Start-Up Investors

UNITED STATES INTERNATIONAL TRADE COMMISSION WASHINGTON, DC 20436

Business Method Patents, Innovation, and Policy

Transcription:

JUSTIFICATION AND CRITIQUE OF THE PATENT SYSTEM DEAN CHEN PHIL 170, DUKE UNIVERSITY NOVEMBER 12 TH, 2011 INTRODUCTION Intellectual property protection is a relatively recent development in human history. Patent law originated in 16 th century Britain. In order to stimulate economic progress, the British crown granted monopoly privileges as incentives for foreign industrialists to establish and develop new industries in Britain. The parliament soon realized the significance of this privilege. Over the following two centuries, the British parliament took control of monopoly grants by integrating them in to common law. As intellectual property rights were made available to the masses in 18 th century Britain, the fundamentals of modern patent law such as novelty as and invention documentation were developed through case law. 1 The institution surrounding intellectual property has become an edifice in the modern global economy. In 1996, the World Trade Organization s Agreement on Trade- Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights established a minimum required level of intellectual property protection among its 153 member nations. 2 In 2008, worldwide patent applications doubled from 1 to 2 million in just a decade. Corporations worldwide invested over $600 billion in to the research and development of valuable intellectual property, with the goal of increasing their competitiveness in the global marketplace for years to come. 3 However, the modern patent system is replacing one market failure with another by using monopoly rights to incentivize the provision of public goods. Is the most efficient system for incentivizing innovation? This paper will summarize the justification for and discuss the troublesome inefficiencies of the modern patent system. INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY which one man has invented, all the world can imitate Bentham (1839) Ownership of property is as ancient as human history. However, the notion of treating knowledge as property did not exist until the 19 th century. 4 Intellectual property is unlike most private physical property, it is a public good, having the 1 Moser, P. (2003). How Do Patent Laws Influence Innovation?. Nber Working Paper Series. 2 World Trade Organization. (2011). TRIPS material on the WTO website. Retrieved 2011, from World Trade Organization: http://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/trips_e/trips_e.htm 3 Institute for Prospective Technological Studies. (2008). The 2009 EU Industrial R&D Investment Scoreboard. European Commission. 4 Moser, P. (2003). How Do Patent Laws Influence Innovation?. Nber Working Paper Series.

qualities of non- excludability and non- rivalrous. Knowledge is non- excludable because is very difficult to prevent others from using or distributing ideas especially given the vast improvements to communication technology over the past century. However, the non- rivalrous nature of ideas means that use by one individual does not preclude use by another; there is no scarcity associated with the use of ideas. For much of human history, there wasn t incentive to prevent others from enjoying the benefits of one s own knowledge given that it was at no cost to the inventor in most cases. Capitalism changed the way mankind perceived knowledge and profit. The establishment of massive competitive markets where the products of knowledge can generate enormous profit added a wrinkle to the non- rivalrous nature of ideas. Capitalism drastically increased the profitability of knowledge by giving innovative products a significantly larger consumer base. Imitators impose a cost on the inventor by reducing the price and/or quantity sold of the original product. Since knowledge is non- excludable, imitators will saturate the market with competitive products up to the point where there is no profit to be had. In a perfectly competitive market, economics anticipate that the inventor would be deprived of all economic profit that would have resulted from his invention. Inventions would not be profitable in a competitive market if it was not protected from imitators and inventors will lose some incentive to innovate. A tragedy of the commons occurs and the lack of economic incentive constrains the rate of innovation. Given the profound impact of innovation on economic growth and standard of living, adequately managing the incentives for inventors is of outmost importance. INCENTIVE FOR INNOVATION to promote the progress of science and useful arts U.S. Constitution A patent is a type of intellectual property right granted by the U.S. government to exclude others from making, using, offering for sale, or selling the invention for a limited time, typically 20 years. A patent on an invention must be examined by the United States Patent and Trademark Office (USPTO) to be novel, non- obvious and of utility. 5 In exchange for the documentation and contribution of the invention to the public domain at the expiration of the patent the inventor is granted a temporary monopoly. Patents solve the tragedy of commons problem by the promise of a lucrative monopoly when the idea be productized. Economists strong aversion to monopolies is motivated by the belief that monopolies are inherently inefficient. A monopoly maximizes profit by artificially reducing supply and charging above- cost prices. This imposes a deadweight loss in 5 United States Patent and Trademark Office. (2011). Patents. Retrieved 2011, from United States Patent and Trademark Office: http://www.uspto.gov/patents/index.jsp

society from the loss of consumer surplus from individuals who would have otherwise purchased the good at the lower at- cost price. 6 Monopolies also have disastrous consequences for social justice. The excess profit from monopolistic pricing is extracted from lost consumer surplus; the interest of monopolies is enhanced at the expense of consumers (Hettinger, 1989). The United States Department of Justice does not take the abuse of monopolistic power lightly and has extensive anti- trust law to prevent mergers that would result in giving a firm a market dominate position and the exploitation of consumers by market dominate firms artificially limiting their supply. Patents are justified under the assumption that it is socially efficient for inventors to be rewarded with a limited time monopoly in exchange for the contribution of their invention to society at the end of the 20- year term; the social enhancement from innovative activity should balance out the losses from monopolistic inefficiency. 7 Due to the adverse consequences of monopolies on society, the argument for the necessity of granting monopolies must be bulletproof. If patents are necessary incentives for a certain innovations such that those innovations would not have occurred then patents for those innovations can be justified as pareto- improving; consumers will be better off with the products of those inventions at higher prices and lower quantity than none at all. It is important to note that in the context of the incentive argument above, patent law is a means to an end. The party of interest is the consumer, not the producer; the goal is to maximize consumer surplus. No opinion is given regarding whether inventors are entitled to the monopoly profit generated from their ideas. 8 CRITIQUES patents have not been a positive force Worldwide Patent Counsel, Cisco 9 Fundamental to the justification of the patent system is that the promise of monopoly profit is necessary to incentivize inventors to invent. However, a wide range of evidence has shown that this foundation is shaky at best. By surveying hundreds of significant new technologies, Lemley (2011) showed that teams near simultaneously and independently invented almost all of these technologies. This supports the view that most patented inventions are social progressions, driven be market demand or the availability of new materials, not novel and non- obvious. Further more, many of the truly unique and innovative inventions that did not fall in the above category were shown to be accidental, not the result of a conscious effort to invent. 6 Stigler, G. J. (2008). Monopoly. Retrieved 2011, from The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics: http://www.econlib.org/library/enc/monopoly.html 7 Axel, G., Marciano, A., & Strowel, A. Intellectual Property and Theories of Justice. England: Palgrave Macmillan. 8 Hettinger, E. C. (1989). Justifying Intellectual Property. Philosophy & Public Affairs, 18 (1), 31-52. 9 Barr, R. (2002, 2 28). Statement of Robert Barr. Retrieved 12 13, 2011, from Federal Trade Commission: http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/barrrobert.doc

The belief that only large sums of money can incentivize innovation is also contradicted by history. For example, truly innovative advancements in technology were made during the Renaissance with little regard for profit including the invention of: clocks, eyeglasses, flush toilet, microscopes, telescopes, printing press, artillery, rockets and submarine. In a empirical investigation of the effects of patent law on innovation in the 19 th century, Moser (2003) concluded that there was no significant difference in the level of innovation among countries with and without patent law. There are millions of researchers around the world today motivated not by profit but by the desire to do good, their inherit curiosity and the ambition for prestige. Even profit- oriented corporations like Cisco may not need the incentive of monopoly profits to innovate. According to Barr (2002), the Worldwide Patent Counsel of Cisco: Everything we have done to create new products would have been done even if we could not obtain patents on the innovations and inventions contained in these products. I know this because no one has ever asked me can we patent this? before deciding whether to invest time and resources into product development. Regardless of whether new products will be protected from imitators, corporations will need to meet customer demands by consistently bringing new and innovative products to market. A successful and profitable product requires much more than a good idea, being the first to launch of an innovative product is a huge. Apple is one example of a successful company with wildly profitable products that always stays one step ahead of its sea of imitators and competitors. Even if monopoly profit isn t necessary for incentivizing innovation, it may still do more good than harm by stimulating a faster rate of innovation or stimulating a higher quality/quantity of innovation. Economics has not been able to offer a satisfying answer to this dilemma given the complexity of the issue. There is a delicate balance between increasing competition and derivative innovations through weaker patent protection and incentivizing innovation through stronger patent protection. (Denicolo, 1996) However, models have shown that overly broad or lengthy patent protection can be detrimental to technical progress given that knowledge is both the input and output of innovation (Hall, 2007). The fast moving field of technology is one victim to the over extension of patent protection. Patent infringement is considered unavoidable by even the most well capitalized and resourceful tech companies. 10 10 Barr, R. (2002, 2 28). Statement of Robert Barr. Retrieved 12 13, 2011, from Federal Trade Commission: http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/barrrobert.doc

There are as many as 250,000 patent claims involved with the smart phone 11 and 15,000 patents involved with e- commerce 12. Even if one could accomplish the daunting task of identifying every potential infringement, it would be impossible negotiating licenses with all parties involved in a timely manner. To solve this problem technology companies stockpile patents that would not have otherwise been filed for the sole purpose of having ammunition to defend against infringement suits from other large tech companies. 13 CONCLUSION The design of the patent institution has a profound influence on innovation. Determining the efficiency of the patent system is a complex affair that can t be addressed by purely empirical methods. However, it is clear that there are serious problems with the system that needs to be resolved going forward. 11 Arthur, C. (2011, 8 4). Apple using 'bogus' patents to make Android more expensive, says Google. Retrieved 2011, from The Guardian: http://www.guardian.co.uk/technology/2011/aug/04/apple- patents- android- expensive- google 12 Los Angeles Times. (2003, 2 8). E- Commerce Battles 'Me'- Commerce. Retrieved 2011, from David Streitfeld: http://web.archive.org/web/20080309060603/http://www.davidstreitfeld.com/archive/technolog y/extortion.shtml 13 Barr, R. (2002, 2 28). Statement of Robert Barr. Retrieved 12 13, 2011, from Federal Trade Commission: http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/barrrobert.doc

REFERENCES United States Patent and Trademark Office. (2011). Patents. Retrieved 2011, from United States Patent and Trademark Office: http://www.uspto.gov/patents/index.jsp World Trade Organization. (2011). TRIPS material on the WTO website. Retrieved 2011, from World Trade Organization: http://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/trips_e/trips_e.htm Axel, G., Marciano, A., & Strowel, A. Intellectual Property and Theories of Justice. England: Palgrave Macmillan. Barr, R. (2002, 2 28). Statement of Robert Barr. Retrieved 12 13, 2011, from Federal Trade Commission: http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/barrrobert.doc Bentham, J. (1839). The Works of Jeremy Bentham. (J. Bowring, Ed.) Retrieved 12 2011, from The Online Library of Liberty: http://oll.libertyfund.org/title/1922 Denicolo, V. (1996). Patent Races and Optimal Patent Breadth and Length. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 44 (3), 249-265. Graham v. John Deere Co., 383 U.S. 1 (Supreme Court of the United States Feburary 21, 1965). Institute for Prospective Technological Studies. (2008). The 2009 EU Industrial R&D Investment Scoreboard. European Commission. Hall, B. H. (2007). Patents and patent policy. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 23 (4), 568-587. Hettinger, E. C. (1989). Justifying Intellectual Property. Philosophy & Public Affairs, 18 (1), 31-52. Landes, W. M., & Posner, R. (2003). The economic structure of intellectual property law. Harvard University Press. Lemley, M. A. (2011, 7 12). The Myth of the Sole Inventor. Stanford Public Law Working Paper No. 1856610. Los Angeles Times. (2003, 2 8). E- Commerce Battles 'Me'- Commerce. Retrieved 2011, from David Streitfeld: http://web.archive.org/web/20080309060603/http://www.davidstreitfeld.com/a rchive/technology/extortion.shtml Machlup, F. (1985). An Economic Review of the Patent System. United States Senate, Committee on the Judiciary. Washington: United States Government Printing Office. Merges, R. P. (2011). Justifying Intellectual Property. Harvard University Press. Moser, P. (2003). How Do Patent Laws Influence Innovation?. Nber Working Paper Series. Mossof, A. (2003). Rethinking the development of patents : an intellectual history, 1550-1800. East Lansing, Michigan: Michigan State University. Shapiro, C. (2004). Patent System Reform: Economic Analysis and Critique. Berkeley Technology Law Journal, 1018-1047. Stigler, G. J. (2008). Monopoly. Retrieved 2011, from The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics: http://www.econlib.org/library/enc/monopoly.html Stiglitz, J. (1999). Knowledge as a Global Public Good. In I. G. Inge Kaul, Global Public Goods: International Cooperation in the 21st Century (pp. 308-325). New York: Oxford University Press.