INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY AND ECONOMIC GROWTH

Similar documents
Intellectual Property Rights and Economic Growth: Evidence from A Cross-Country Data of Developing Countries

Economics of IPRs and patents

National Intellectual Property Systems, Innovation and Economic Development Framework for Country Analysis. Dominique Guellec

Innovation, Creativity, and Intellectual Property Rights

Globalizing IPR Protection: How Important Might RTAs Be?

The 45 Adopted Recommendations under the WIPO Development Agenda

Trade Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights and Developing countries

Development. Prepared for Intellectual Property Task Force meeting 2009 University of Manchester, June 22-23, 2009

WIPO Development Agenda

Establishing a Development Agenda for the World Intellectual Property Organization

TRIPS-Plus Provisions and Access to Technologies:

University IP and Technology Management. University IP and Technology Management

Flexibilities in the Patent System

Patent Protection, Technological Efforts, and Exports: An Empirical Investigation

Intellectual Property Rights and Endogenous Economic Growth: uncovering the main gaps in the research agenda

Working Party of the Trade Committee

The Role of Effective Intellectual Property Management in Enhancing the Competitiveness of Small and Medium-sized Enterprises (SMEs)

The role of IP in economic development: the case of China

The role of IP and other enabling factors for innovation and uptake of climate relevant technologies WIPO Green technology database and services

WIPO-IFIA INTERNATIONAL SYMPOSIUM ON THE COMMERCIALIZATION OF INVENTIONS IN THE GLOBAL MARKET

Follow this and additional works at: Part of the Law Commons

COMPETITIVNESS, INNOVATION AND GROWTH: THE CASE OF MACEDONIA

Review essay. Intellectual property regulation and international trade: national and global economic perspectives. Alexander Cuntz

Intellectual property rights, political risk and economic growth in developing countries

Patents & Innovation In the Pharmaceutical Industry: Literature Review. Jonathan Gock POL 459 Prof. Hira Fall 09

INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT. Keith E. Maskus Professor of Economics University of Colorado, Boulder

GENEVA COMMITTEE ON DEVELOPMENT AND INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY (CDIP) Fifth Session Geneva, April 26 to 30, 2010

Impact of the International Patent System on Productivity and Technology Diffusion

Intellectual Property: Balancing Incentives with Competitive Access

Comments of the AMERICAN INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW ASSOCIATION. Regarding

Intellectual Property Rights and Development CARLOS M. CORREA

Construction and Measure of the Evaluation Index System of Regional Soft Power - Taking Shandong Province as an Example

GENEVA WIPO GENERAL ASSEMBLY. Thirty-First (15 th Extraordinary) Session Geneva, September 27 to October 5, 2004

"Competition Policy and Intellectual Property Rights in the Republic of Latvia since 1991" (the working title)

TRIPS, FTAs and BITs: Impact on Domestic IP- and Innovation Strategies in Developing Countries

Patents, trade and foreign direct investment in the European Union

Under the Patronage of His Highness Sayyid Faisal bin Ali Al Said Minister for National Heritage and Culture

I Economic Growth 5. Second Edition. Robert J. Barro Xavier Sala-i-Martin. The MIT Press Cambridge, Massachusetts London, England

Indicators of the Relative Importance of IPRs in Developing Countries

Research on the Impact of R&D Investment on Firm Performance in China's Internet of Things Industry

An Introduction to China s Science and Technology Policy

SCIENCE-INDUSTRY COOPERATION: THE ISSUES OF PATENTING AND COMMERCIALIZATION

UNCTAD Ad Hoc Expert Meeting on the Green Economy: Trade and Sustainable Development Implications November

18 The Impact of Revisions of the Patent System on Innovation in the Pharmaceutical Industry (*)

Kazakhstan Way of Innovation Clusterization K. Mukhtarova Al-Farabi Kazak National University, Almaty, Kazakhstan

INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS AND THE WTO

OECD Innovation Strategy: Key Findings

Keynote Address by Dr Rob Davies Minister of Trade and Industry of South Africa

Intellectual Property Initiatives

BASED ECONOMIES. Nicholas S. Vonortas

OECD s Innovation Strategy: Key Findings and Policy Messages

Getting Started. This Lecture

Committee on Development and Intellectual Property (CDIP)

THE IMPLICATIONS OF THE KNOWLEDGE-BASED ECONOMY FOR FUTURE SCIENCE AND TECHNOLOGY POLICIES

Building an enterprise-centred innovation system

Practical measures to encourage the diffusion of green technologies: Licensing Fast tracking of green patents The GreenXchange Platform

The International Legal Policy in the Field of Technology Transfer and the Intellectual Property Rights: Some Controversial Issues

the Companies and Intellectual Property Commission of South Africa (CIPC)

Innovation and Intellectual Property Issues for Debate

A Test on Causality Relationship between Intellectual Property Rights Protection and Foreign Direct Investment in Malaysia

WIPO ASIAN REGIONAL SEMINAR ON AN INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY STRATEGY FOR SMALL AND MEDIUM-SIZED ENTERPRISES (SMEs)

CRS Report for Congress

Government s Role in Promoting the Use of ICT

Does the Protection of Foreign Intellectual Property Rights Stimulate Innovation in the US?roie_

The Green Economy: Trade and Sustainable Development Implications. From Rio to Rio:Technology Transfer, Innovation and Intellectual Property

International IP. Prof. Eric E. Johnson. General Principles

WIPO Sub-Regional Workshop on Patent Policy and its Legislative Implementation

Submission to the Productivity Commission inquiry into Intellectual Property Arrangements

Oesterreichische Nationalbank. Eurosystem. Workshops Proceedings of OeNB Workshops. Current Issues of Economic Growth. March 5, No.

INNOVATION AND ECONOMIC GROWTH CASE STUDY CHINA AFTER THE WTO

Innovation Strategies o f the BRICKS: Different Strategies, Different Results. November 18, 2008

IP and Technology Management for Universities

History of the WIPO Development Agenda

Introduction ROMAN MOSKALYK**

WIPO REGIONAL SEMINAR ON SUPPORT SERVICES FOR INVENTORS, VALUATION AND COMMERCIALIZATION OF INVENTIONS AND RESEARCH RESULTS

Introduction to the SMEs Division of WIPO

The Impacts of Post-TRIPS Patent Reforms on the Structure of Exports

INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS IN THE WORLD ECONOMY

Course 1.1 Introduction to Innovation: Role of STI for Growth and Sustainable Development UN-Wide Capacity Building Workshop on Technology for

Patenting Strategies. The First Steps. Patenting Strategies / Bernhard Nussbaumer, 12/17/2009 1

RWANDA EXPERIENCE RUHIMA BLAISE OFFICE OF THE REGISTRAR GENERAL RWANDA DEVELOPEMENT BOARD

An Essential Health and Biomedical R&D Treaty

WIPO-WTO Colloquium for Teachers of Intellectual Property

Intellectual property rights: Issues and challenges in Malaysian manufacturing firms

PROTECTION OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY

Intellectual Property Rights: Economic Principles and Trade Rules

UNCTAD-ICTSD Project on IPRs and Sustainable Development

The Impacts of Post-TRIPS Patent Reforms on the Structure of Exports. Keith E. Maskus 1 Lei Yang

INTELLECTUAL PROPERY RIGHTS: ECONOMY Vs SCIENCE &TECHNOLOGY. Sankar Narayanan.S System Analyst, Anna University Coimbatore

Does Intellectual Property Promote Innovation? Towards an Understanding of Intellectual Property and World Public Goods

Changing role of the State in Innovative Activity The Indian Experience. Sunil Mani

OECD Science, Technology and Industry Outlook 2008: Highlights

High Level Seminar on the Creative Economy and Copyright as Pathways to Sustainable Development. UN-ESCAP/ WIPO, Bangkok December 6, 2017

Chinese Intellectual Property Right Regime and Independent Innovation of Enterprises

Technology Strategy for Managers and Entrepreneurs

What is Intellectual Property?

Patent Protection, Innovation Rate and Welfare

International Technology Transfer & Intellectual Property Rights

OECD-INADEM Workshop on

Concept Note Africa Innovation Summit Satellite Event: South Africa 6 8 June 2018 The Venue, Pretoria

Transcription:

International Journal of Economics, Commerce and Management United Kingdom Vol. IV, Issue 2, February 2016 http://ijecm.co.uk/ ISSN 2348 0386 INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY AND ECONOMIC GROWTH A REVIEW OF EMPIRICAL STUDIES Mirësi Çela PhD Candidate, A. Xhuvani University, Albania Faculty of Economy, Department of Business Administration, Elbasan, Albania celamiresi@gmail.com; miresi.cela@uniel.edu.al Abstract In recent decades the issue of Intellectual property rights (IPRs) protection has been at the center of public policy debates. Today, IP rights are recognized as an important economic mechanism, an intellectual currency of sorts, that encourages research and development (R&D), creation and innovation in several significant ways. So innovation is important for economic growth, but IPR protection is important for innovation, this way IPR protection becomes important for the economic growth too. The aim of the paper is to make a review of the empirical studies done by different scholars, to show evidence of the relation that exists between IPR protection and economic growth, in developed and developing countries. What happens when strengthening the IPR protection for these countries? At the end the paper concludes that the relationship between intellectual property and economic growth is not so clear. IPR protection impacts on growth rates will differ across countries, depending on their level of development. Not all empirical studies conclude in a positive impact between IPR protection and growth. Keywords: Intellectual Property Rights, IPR Protection, Economic Growth, Innovation, R&D INTRODUCTION Intellectual property rights (IPR) - the copyrights, patents, trademarks and similar rights upon which the lion s share of creative and innovative products and services rely have a vital role in growing the economies of developed and developing countries all over the world, in spurring innovation, in giving large and small firms a range of tools to help drive their success, and in benefiting consumers and society through a continuous stream of innovative, competitive Licensed under Creative Common Page 774

International Journal of Economics, Commerce and Management, United Kingdom products and services and an expansion of society s overall state of knowledge. Intellectual property rights protection works in five main areas: 1. Intellectual Property benefits the economy 2. Intellectual Property protection promotes innovation 3. Intellectual Property protection helps firms monetize their innovations and grow 4. Intellectual Property protection help SMEs 5. Intellectual Property protection benefits consumers and society As the knowledge economy advances, more and more of the value that firms and the overall economy achieve will come from high value-added intangibles including IP in inventions, brands and works. In many companies even now, 80% or more of their market value is attributable to intangibles, including IP. In some small companies, the only value is the intellectual property they own in an exciting new innovation that they have developed. IPR has truly become an intellectual currency helping to promote economic growth, company competitiveness and innovation world-wide (ICC, 2003). What is the Relationship between IPR Protection and Economic Growth? The different forms of intellectual property patent, copyright, trademark and various other similar legal rights traditionally were viewed as state protections of natural or moral rights. Today, however, IP rights are recognized as an important economic mechanism, an intellectual currency of sorts, that encourages research and development (R&D), creation and innovation in several significant ways (Guellec, 2007). IPR promotes innovation by providing the legal and economic framework for market-based incentives and rewards that: pay for research and development, support the promotion and distribution of the innovations that are thus developed, in the form of products, services and processes in the market, promote cultural expression and diversity, make technologies more widely available through the mechanism of licensing, Increase society s overall State of knowledge through the information disclosed in patent applications and publications, promote technology transfers, and broaden the dissemination of government - funded R&D. The link between IPR protection and growth passes through innovation. So innovation is important for economic growth, but IPR protection is important for innovation, this way IPR protection becomes important for the economic growth too. Licensed under Creative Common Page 775

Mirësi Countries tend to acquire improved technologies, through a variety of channels like: Domestic innovation; Trade; FDI; Licensing; Imitation; Piracy. High, middle and low- income countries differ between them among other things, on the relative importance of these channels. So their level of development determines the way they get the improved technology. What happens when strengthening the IPR protection for these countries? This will impact these channels in different ways and its impact on growth rates will differ across countries, depending on their level of development. IPRS Protection and Economic Growth: Empirical Evidence A few studies have investigated the impact of IPR protection on cross-country growth. Falvey et al., (2004) in their study use panel data for 80 countries and for four five- year periods to address the impact of IPR protection on economic growth. Including an of IPR protection in a standard empirical growth model they find that there is a positive and generally significant relationship between the extent of IPR protection in a country and its growth rate. They use threshold regression techniques to examine if the relationship between IPR protection and output growth depends upon a third factor. Their results suggest that the relationship between IPR protection and growth depends upon level of development, with proxy by initial GDP per capita. For low- and high - income countries they find that stronger IPR protection significantly improves growth, but for middle -income countries no such relationship is found. As authors state the results for high-income countries are largely as expected, because in these countries undertake innovation, so to encourage further innovation, innovators should be allowed to profit from their inventions. In low- income countries strong IPR protection encourages imports and inward FDI that encourage growth without adversely affecting domestic imitative activities. Middle income countries do not engage in innovative activities, they rely on imitative activities. The lack of a relationship between IPR protection and growth in these countries is likely to reflect two opposing forces. The positive impact of IPR protection on growth that works indirectly through trade and FDI is being offset by a negative impact slowing knowledge diffusion and discouraging imitation. Despite the lack of evidence for a significant relationship between IPR protection and growth for middle income countries in no case do they find evidence of a negative relationship between IPR protection and growth. According to Falvey et al., (2004) the last conclusion is important because the TRIPS Agreement imposes minimum standards of IPR protection on WTO members (during The Licensed under Creative Common Page 776

International Journal of Economics, Commerce and Management, United Kingdom Uruguay Round in 1994, when WTO was established from GATT, more specifically the TRIPS agreement was signed, whose aim was to establish minimum standards of IPR protection by all WTO members up to 2006. On this evidence at least, developing countries joining WTO should be able to take advantage of broad benefits of freer trade without sacrificing growth in order to meet the accompanying TRIPs obligations. Gould and Gruben (1996) estimate a growth model on a cross-section of up to 95 countries with data averaged over the period 1960-88, including in their regression the IPR measure of Rapp and Rozek (1990). They find IPR protection has a significant positive impact on growth. Gould and Gruben (1996) examine whether IPR protection affects growth in open versus closed economies differently, by interacting their measure of IPRs with three measures of a country s trade orientation. Their results suggest that IPR protection can have a slightly larger impact on growth in open economies, but only for one measure is the coefficient ever significant and even then its significance is not robust to the inclusion of other variables. Thompson and Rushing (1996) estimate cross-section growth regressions including up to 112 countries for the period 1970-85, again using the Rapp and Rozek measure. While they find positive coefficients on the IPR variable, they are never significant. Both these studies also consider non-linearity in the growth-ipr relationship. Thompson & Rushing (1996) employ a switching regression model to examine whether increased IPR protection (more specifically patent protection) is more beneficial once a country has reached a particular level of development, as measured by initial GDP per capita. Their results indicate a break point at an initial level of GDP of $3,400 (with 1980 dollars). For countries below this no relationship between IPR protection and growth is found, but above it a positive and significant relationship is found. Thompson and Rushing (1999) in their extended study of 1996, include data from 55 countries, using regression techniques on a cross-section of data over the period 1971-1990. As dependent variable they use growth of real GDP per capita; ratio of total factor productivity (TFP is a derived measure of technology change) in 1971 to that in 1990; and the Rapp and Rozek Index of IPRs. They conclude IPR protection has a positive impact on TFP in relatively rich countries, which in turn impacts positively upon output growth. More recently (Kanwar & Evenson,( 2003) estimate a panel model for two periods and up to 32 countries using the Ginarte and Park (1997) of IPRs. They aim to measure the impact of IPR protection on innovation directly using as their explanatory variable R&D investment as a proportion of GNP. They find that IPRs have a positive and significant impact Licensed under Creative Common Page 777

Mirësi on R&D investment and conclude that stronger IPR protection can help spur innovation and technological progress, which in turn should positively impact on growth. Chen & Puttitanun (2005) in their study argue that IP protection impacts on developing countries because it can encourage domestic innovative activities (they measured it by patent applications). According to them, domestic innovations have a U-shaped relationship with Gross National Products (GNP) and IPP. The possible existence of an empirical U-shaped curve between IPRs and per capita GNP has been noticed also, by Maskus (2000) and by Primo Braga et al. (2000). Initially, when a country has a low level of economic development, technological abilities will not have reached the level to allow for creativity, and such countries ' focus will therefore be primarily imitating foreign technologies, and a low level IPP policy is appropriate. However, when technological abilities increases to a certain level, increased protection is needed to encourage domestic innovation activities. The study empirically tested 64 developing countries (1975-2000), and this result is in line with earlier studies about the impact of IP on economic growth.(chen & Puttitanun, 2005). These authors conclude that IP protection does not impact on economic growth independently or directly, but interacts with variables such as trade openness, national competitiveness, IP Index, human capital, FDI and government policy. Leger (2006) also analyzed the relationship between IPRs and innovation using a novel panel data-set of least developed countries and industrialized countries and found that IP protection was significant only at a low level for developing countries. Table 1: Empirical studies on the relationship between IPR protection and economic growth Study Sample and method Dependent variable(s) IPR Results Gould and Gruben (1996) 95 countries Cross section with data averaged over the period 1960-1988 Growth of real GDP per capita Rapp and Rozek IPR protection has a positive impact on growth which is slightly stronger in more open economies. Thompson and Rushing (1996) 112 countries ; Cross section with data averaged over the period 1970-1985 Growth of real GDP per capita Rapp and Rozek IPR protection (patent protection) has a positive impact on growth only in countries that have reached a certain initial level of GDP per capita. Licensed under Creative Common Page 778

International Journal of Economics, Commerce and Management, United Kingdom Thompson and Rushing (1999) 55 countries Seemingly unrelated regression techniques on a cross-section of data over the period 1971-1990 Growth of real GDP per capita ; Ratio of total factor productivity (TFP-- is a derived measure of technology change) in 1971 to that in 1990; the Rapp and Rozek Index of IPRs. Rapp and Rozek IPR protection has a positive impact on TFP in relatively rich countries, which in turn impacts positively upon output growth. Park (1999) 60 countries, seemingly unrelated regression techniques on a cross -section of data over the period 1960-1990 Growth of real GDP, fraction of GDP invested in physical capital, fraction of GDP invested in human capital, fraction of GDP invested in R&D Ginarte and Park IPR protection has no direct impact on growth. IPR protection has an indirect positive impact on growth through physical capital investment and R&D in the most advanced economies. Kanwar and Evenson (2003) a panel model for two periods and up to 32 countries using the They aim to measure the impact of IPR protection on innovation directly using as their explanatory variable R&D investment as a proportion of GNP. Ginarte and Park (1997) They find that IPRs have a positive and significant impact on R&D investment and conclude that stronger IPR protection can help spur innovation and technological progress, which in turn should positively impact on growth. Falvey et al., (2004) use panel data for 80 countries and for four five- year periods To address the impact of IPR protection on economic growth, they use a standard empirical growth model, with a threshold regression techniques. Ginarte and Park (1997) They find that there is a positive and generally significant relationship between the extent of IPR protection in a country and its growth rate. Is strong IP protection, always better? In recent decades, the broader issue of intellectual property rights (IPR) protection has been at the center of public policy debates. A major argument in favor of stronger IPR is that it stimulates economic growth by protecting innovators from imitation, thereby encouraging innovation. In fact, many countries have strengthened their protection of IPR by reforming their patent systems. Licensed under Creative Common Page 779

Mirësi However, although this view is widely accepted, recent work, both theoretical and empirical, indicates that, in a closed economy, the relationship between IPR protection and economic growth is actually not so clear. Furukawa (2007) in his work shows that IPR protection may not enhance economic growth in an endogenous growth model with costless imitation: that is, stronger is always better is incorrect. Not all empirical studies conclude in a positive impact IPR protection and growth. Furukawa (2007) stated that the relationship between IPR protection and innovation has an inverted-u shape when the impact of accumulated experience on productivity is large enough. From his work results he suggests a role for relaxing IPR protection as a growthenhancing policy. Due to the inverted U-shaped relationship between IPR protection and growth, both too strong and too weak protection hurts innovation and the resulting growth: instead, a balanced approach is required for growth. This can provide insight into the role of IPR protection in economic growth, a topic often raised in public policy discussions. In his paper, Furukawa, also shows that the equilibrium growth rate can be maximized when there is no IPR protection if the natural rate of imitation, which is determined by the economy s fundamentals, is low enough. Therefore, preferred growth-enhancing policies can vary across countries with different potential imitation rates: in countries where imitation hardly takes place, there is no need to protect IPR for innovation and economic growth. Azevedo et al., (2010) after a thorough review of theoretical literature have identified some gaps in the research agenda. In general, this research does not study the direct and net effect of IPR on economic growth. In fact it only analyzes the relationship between IPR-induced factors and economic growth, or the impact of IPR on other economic indicators such as welfare, technological change, FDI, R&D, innovation, etc. This happens because a standard argumentation is adopted, maintaining a strict relation between these elements and economic growth. Despite the divergence of results regarding theoretical studies, most empirical studies find a net positive effect, which means that positive effects of IPR protection outweigh the negative effects. Their study supports the conclusion that there is no clear relationship between IPR and economic growth. Theoretical literature indicates that IPR protection has positive, negative or even ambiguous (or inconclusive) effects on innovation. Licensed under Creative Common Page 780

International Journal of Economics, Commerce and Management, United Kingdom CONCLUDING REMARKS IPR, in their various forms, play a crucial role in innovation systems. Firms invest in innovation activities, find new products or new processes and increase their profits. To prevent the imitation of their innovations, firms can benefit from IPR protection. In recent decades, the broader issue of intellectual property rights (IPR) protection has been at the center of public policy debates, to enforce or not the intellectual property protection? A major argument in favor of stronger IPR is that it stimulates economic growth by protecting innovators from imitation, thereby encouraging innovation. In fact, many countries have strengthened their protection of IPR by reforming their patent systems. Several international agreements, such as the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT), Trade-Related aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS) and (the) World Intellectual Property Organization (WIPO) are concerned with the protection of IPRs. However, although this view is widely accepted, recent work, both theoretical and empirical, indicates that, in a closed economy, the relationship between IPR protection and economic growth is actually not so clear. Despite the divergence of results regarding theoretical studies, most empirical studies find a net positive effect, which means that positive effects of IPR protection outweigh the negative effects. These findings imply that it might be best to allow countries to choose their own IPR system. Specifically, they point out that when the current rich countries were developing they often had weaker IPRs, especially for foreign nationals. A phrase used to summarize this viewpoint is that the rich countries are pulling up the ladder that helped them to climb behind them. Given these points, any move to harmonize IPRs across countries will be controversial. REFERENCES Azevedo, M. L., Silva, S. T., & Afonso, Ó. (2010). Intellectual Property Rights and Endogenous Economic Growth Uncovering the Main Gaps in the Research Agenda. Braga, C. A. P., Fink, C., & Sepulveda, C. P. (2000). Intellectual property rights and economic i development (Vol. 412). World Bank Publications. Chen, Y., & Puttitanun, T. (2005). Intellectual property rights and innovation in developing countries. Journal of Development Economics, 78(2), 474 493. http://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2004.11.005 Falvey, R., Foster, N., & Greenaway, D. (2004). Intellectual Property Rights and Economic Growth. Research Paper Series. Retrieved from http://www.nottingham.ac.uk/gep/documents/papers/2004/04-12.pdf, 12 July 2015 Furukawa, Y. (2007). The protection of intellectual property rights and endogenous growth: Is stronger always better? Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 31, 3644 3670. http://doi.org/10.1016/j.jedc.2007.01.011 Park, W. G. and J.C. Ginarte. 1997. Intellectual Property Rights and Economic Growth. Contemporary Economic Policy XV: 51-61. Licensed under Creative Common Page 781

Mirësi Gould, D. M. and Gruben, W. C. (1996) The role of intellectual property rights in economic growth, Journal of Development Economics, 48, 323-350. Guellec, D. (2007). Patents as an Incentive to Innovate. Guellec, D. and van Pottelsberghe, B., The Economics of the European Patent System, 63-74. ICC. (2003). Intellectual property: powerhouse for innovation and economic growth. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 27(5), 853 873. http://doi.org/10.1016/s0165-1889(02)00018-0 Kanwar, S., & Evenson, R. (2003). Does intellectual property protection spur technological change? Oxford Economic Papers, 55(2), 235 264. http://doi.org/10.1093/oep/55.2.235 Leger, A. (2006). Intellectual Property Rights and Innovation in Developing Countries : Evidence from Panel Data Andréanne Léger, 49(0). Retrieved from http://ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/21407/1/sp06le01.pdf, on 2 July 2015 Maskus, K. E. (2000). The economics of intellectual property rights and globalization: Dancing the dual distortion. In Intellectual Property Rights in the Global Economy (pp. 1 89). Retrieved from http://mattias.ganslandt.info/ipr/maskus_globalization.pdf, on 2 July 2015 Thompson, M. a., & Rushing, F. W. (1996). An Empirical Analysis of the Impact of Patent Protection on Economic Growth. Journal of Economic Development. Retrieved from http://jed.or.kr/full-text/21-2/4.pdf, on 20 June 2015 Thompson, M. A. andf. W. Rushing (1999). An Empirical Analysis of the Impact of Patent Protection on Economic Growth: An Extension, Journal of Economic Development, 24, 67-76.hange?. Oxford Economic Papers, 235-264. Licensed under Creative Common Page 782