Lexis PSL Competition Practice Note

Similar documents
The Revised EU Block Exemption Regulation for Research and Development Agreements

Guidelines on Standardization and Patent Pool Arrangements

IS STANDARDIZATION FOR AUTONOMOUS CARS AROUND THE CORNER? By Shervin Pishevar

WIPO-IFIA INTERNATIONAL SYMPOSIUM ON THE COMMERCIALIZATION OF INVENTIONS IN THE GLOBAL MARKET

(Non-legislative acts) DECISIONS

Translation University of Tokyo Intellectual Property Policy

California State University, Northridge Policy Statement on Inventions and Patents

EL PASO COMMUNITY COLLEGE PROCEDURE

"Competition Policy and Intellectual Property Rights in the Republic of Latvia since 1991" (the working title)

Fact Sheet IP specificities in research for the benefit of SMEs

LAW ON TECHNOLOGY TRANSFER 1998

Slide 25 Advantages and disadvantages of patenting

Patent Due Diligence

Identifying and Managing Joint Inventions

F98-3 Intellectual/Creative Property

Patents, Standards and Antitrust: Patent Pools

EUROPEAN CENTRAL BANK

COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT. pursuant to Article 294(6) of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union

IMPORTANT NOTICE: PLEASE READ CAREFULLY BEFORE INSTALLING THE SOFTWARE: THIS LICENCE AGREEMENT (LICENCE) IS A LEGAL AGREEMENT BETWEEN

Statement of the Communications Authority

COUNCIL OF THE EUROPEAN UNION. Brussels, 19 May 2014 (OR. en) 9879/14 Interinstitutional File: 2013/0165 (COD) ENT 123 MI 428 CODEC 1299

(Text with EEA relevance)

COMMISSION DELEGATED DIRECTIVE (EU).../ of XXX

COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT. accompanying document to the

Innovation Office. Intellectual Property at the Nelson Mandela University: A Brief Introduction. Creating value for tomorrow

Comments on the Commission s draft Guidelines on the application of Article 101 TFEU on technology transfer agreements

Issues at the Intersection of IP and Competition Policy

UNCITRAL Third International Colloquium on Secured Transactions Session on Contractual Guide on IP Licensing (Vienna, March 3, 2010)

Incentive Guidelines. Aid for Research and Development Projects (Tax Credit)

Patent application strategy when, where, what to file?

ACT. dated September 11, on waste electrical and electronic equipment. Chapter 1. General provisions

Details of the Proposal

THE UNIVERSITY OF AUCKLAND INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY CREATED BY STAFF AND STUDENTS POLICY Organisation & Governance

RECOMMENDATIONS. COMMISSION RECOMMENDATION (EU) 2018/790 of 25 April 2018 on access to and preservation of scientific information

(Non-legislative acts) REGULATIONS

Question Q 159. The need and possible means of implementing the Convention on Biodiversity into Patent Laws

Spectrum Release Plan

Standing Committee on the Law of Patents Twenty-Sixth Session

What does the revision of the OECD Privacy Guidelines mean for businesses?

MEDICINE LICENSE TO PUBLISH

Variation of UK Broadband s spectrum access licence for 3.6 GHz spectrum

Mr Hans Hoogervorst International Accounting Standards Board 1 st Floor 30 Cannon Street London EC4M 6XH. MV/288 Mark Vaessen.

CRS Report for Congress

SUMMARY OF THE IMPACT ASSESSMENT

EU Technology Transfer Draft Guidelines: Economic Analysis and Suggestions for Revisions. Carl Shapiro. 25 November 2003

Fiscal 2007 Environmental Technology Verification Pilot Program Implementation Guidelines

ADDENDUM D COMERICA WEB INVOICING TERMS AND CONDITIONS

Ministry of Justice: Call for Evidence on EU Data Protection Proposals

UK Broadband Limited Company Reg No: Spectrum Access 3.5 GHz Licence First Issued: 28/02/17 Licence Number: Rev 1: 11/01/18

COMMISSION IMPLEMENTING DECISION

TRAINING SEMINAR PHARMACEUTICALS AND INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY ACCESS TO MEDICINE: Exploitation of pharmaceutical patents: compulsory licences SESSION 4

Assemblies according to the Pressure Equipment Directive - a consideration provided by the PED-AdCo Group 1 -

Policy Contents. Policy Information. Purpose and Summary. Scope. Published on Policies and Procedures (

ORDER OF THE PRESIDENT OF THE PEOPLE'S REPUBLIC OF CHINA

Intellectual Property

Recognised Spectrum Access (RSA) for Receive Only Earth Stations Statement on the making of regulations to introduce RSA in the frequency bands 7850

BEMFV. Order on the procedure for providing proof as regards limiting exposure to. electromagnetic fields

SATELLITE NETWORK NOTIFICATION AND COORDINATION REGULATIONS 2007 BR 94/2007

Justice Select Committee: Inquiry on EU Data Protection Framework Proposals

The 45 Adopted Recommendations under the WIPO Development Agenda

POLICY PHILOSOPHY DEFINITIONS AC.2.11 INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY. Programs and Curriculum. APPROVED: Chair, on Behalf of SAIT s Board of Governors

COMMISSION DELEGATED DIRECTIVE../ /EU. of XXX

Spectrum Licence Wireless Cable Service (500 & 600 MHz Band)

Action: Notice of an application for an order under sections 6(c), 12(d)(1)(J), and 57(c) of the

Intellectual Property Policy. DNDi POLICIES

Case No COMP/M KKR / BOSCH TELECOM PRIVATE NETWORKS. REGULATION (EEC) No 4064/89 MERGER PROCEDURE

Ocean Energy Europe Privacy Policy

Dr. Biswajit Dhar Professor, Jawaharlal Nehru University, India and Member DA9 Advisory Board

(Acts whose publication is obligatory) of 9 March 2005

RESPONSE. SECOND 700 MHz SPECTRUM POLICY CONSULTATION DOCUMENT

IAB Europe Guidance THE DEFINITION OF PERSONAL DATA. IAB Europe GDPR Implementation Working Group WHITE PAPER

ERC/DEC/(01)07 EUROPEAN RADIOCOMMUNICATIONS COMMITTEE

Telecommunication Policy, 2060 (2004)

New York University University Policies

EU Sports Law edgehill.ac.uk

April 21, By to:

POLICY ON INVENTIONS AND SOFTWARE

Statement on variation of 900 MHz and 1800 MHz Wireless Telegraphy Act licences

COMMISSION DELEGATED DIRECTIVE../ /EU. of XXX

Patentability of Computer-Implemented Inventions in the field of Computer Security

Slide 15 The "social contract" implicit in the patent system

19 Progressive Development of Protection Framework for Pharmaceutical Invention under the TRIPS Agreement Focusing on Patent Rights

Impact and Innovation in H2020 Proposals and projects

Intellectual Property Ownership and Disposition Policy

GUIDELINES FOR THE APPLICATION FOR PUBLIC RADIOCOMMUNICATIONS SERVICE (PRS) LICENCES

Approved 09 December 2011

Patents. What is a patent? What is the United States Patent and Trademark Office (USPTO)? What types of patents are available in the United States?

ITU/ITSO Workshop on Satellite Communications, AFRALTI, Nairobi Kenya, 17-21, July, Policy and Regulatory Guidelines for Satellite Services

Intellectual Property

DNVGL-CG-0214 Edition September 2016

Anita Pissolito Campos Nascimento & Mourão Advogados. Anita Pissolito Campos Nascimento e Mourão Advogados

Case M ACTIVISION BLIZZARD / KING. REGULATION (EC) No 139/2004 MERGER PROCEDURE. Article 6(1)(b) NON-OPPOSITION Date: 12/02/2016

COLLABORATIVE R&D & IP ISSUES IN TECHNOLOGY TRANSFER IN UNIVERSITY SYSTEM

UW REGULATION Patents and Copyrights

Strategic Patenting and Registration of Healthcare Products

National Standard of the People s Republic of China

Submission to the Productivity Commission inquiry into Intellectual Property Arrangements

ECB-PUBLIC. OPINION OF THE EUROPEAN CENTRAL BANK of 16 July 2014 on the competence for coin issuance (CON/2014/56)

PATENT PROTECTION FOR PHARMACEUTICAL PRODUCTS IN CANADA CHRONOLOGY OF SIGNIFICANT EVENTS

CAMD Transition Sub Group FAQ IVDR Transitional provisions

Transcription:

Lexis PSL Competition Practice Note Research and development Produced in partnership with K&L Gates LLP Research and Development (R&D ) are under which two or more parties agree to jointly execute research work and/or jointly develop the results of the research. Such can be highly effective in driving innovation and economic progress as they often combine complementary skills and assets, and thus result in improved or new products and technologies being developed and marketed more cheaply and rapidly than would otherwise be the case. They can also facilitate a wider dissemination of knowledge, which may trigger further innovation. Accordingly, EU competition law generally accepts that certain contractual restrictions on the parties independent activities may be necessary in order to encourage joint R&D initiatives. However, restrictions in R&D are sometimes designed to, or have the effect of, restricting competition. It is therefore essential to carefully analyse an R&D agreement between actual and potential competitors to ensure it does not fall foul of the law. See further, Applying EU competition law to research and development -worked examples. Potential competition concerns Article 101(1) of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (TFEU) prohibits, the object or effect of which is to restrict competition. Art 101(1) TFEU Most R&D do not fall under Article 101(1) TFEU, in particular where they relate to cooperation in R&D at an early stage, far removed from the exploitation of possible results. EU horizontal guidelines, para 129 However, R&D may sometimes infringe Article 101(1) TFEU in the following ways: first, they may reduce or slow down innovation, leading to fewer or inferior products coming to the market later than they otherwise would second, if the parties are competitors on a product or technology market, the agreement may reduce significantly competition between them outside the scope of the agreement, or it may make anti-competitive coordination between them likely, thereby leading to higher prices third, where at least one party has a significant degree of market power (which does not necessarily amount to dominance) the agreement may result in other competitors access to a key technology being foreclosed, thus enabling the parties to exclusively exploit the results of that technology to the detriment of other market players. EU horizontal guidelines, para 127 In assessing the competition risks of an R&D agreement, it is important to identify and define all the markets that may potentially be affected. This involves identifying those products, technologies or R&D efforts that will act as the main competitive constraints on the parties. The relevant market(s) may be: EU horizontal guidelines, para 112 an existing market-for example, where the R&D is directed towards slight improvements or variations in a product or technology an entirely new market-for example, because the R&D is aimed at creating an innovative product, such as a vaccine for a previously incurable disease a market somewhere in between the above two extremes-for example, where the R&D results in a product or technology which, over time, replaces existing ones (such as MP3 players replacing CDs). In these circumstances, the EU Horizontal Guidelines (the guidelines) state that a careful analysis of those situations may have to cover both existing markets and the impact of the agreement on innovation; and/or a neighbouring product or technology market-eg where the R&D concerns an input into those markets.

Framework for assessing R&D The following steps should be followed to determine whether an R&D agreement complies with Article 101(1) TFEU: First, all horizontal between the companies engaging in the joint R&D should be assessed according to the European Commission s guidelines on assessing the compatibility of an individual horizontal agreement with Article 101(1) TFEU. EU horizontal guidelines This involves applying to each horizontal agreement the general assessment criteria described in the Guidelines, including determining whether the R&D agreement is caught by Article 101(1) TFEU in the first place; see further, Competition issues impacting horizontal commercial. Second, where the parties combined market share does not exceed 25%, it should be determined whether the conditions of the European Commission s block exemption regulation regarding R&D are fulfilled. An agreement that benefits from the R&D Block Exemption, the conditions for which are considered below, will be automatically valid and enforceable as a matter of EU competition law. Regulation 1217/2010 Third, if an agreement falls outside the R&D Block Exemption, a case-by-case analysis is required to ensure it does not violate competition law. This involves applying the specific assessment criteria described in the Guidelines in relation to R&D, considered below. Finally, even if the above assessment leads to the conclusion that the R&D agreement does not give rise to competition concerns, it will be necessary to examine all relevant vertical between the parties (if any) for potential competition issues there. The latter assessment will follow the rules of the European Commission s Block Exemption Regulation on Vertical Restraints (the Vertical Block Exemption ) and accompanying guidelines (the Guidelines on Vertical Restraints ). See further Competition issues impacting vertical commercial. Commission Regulation (EU) 330/2010 EU vertical restraints guidelines Application of R&D block exemption For an agreement to benefit from automatic exemption under the R&D Block Exemption: the parties combined market share must fall within the specified threshold the agreement must fall within one of six defined categories of agreement the agreement must meet certain conditions for exemption ; and the agreement must not contain any hardcore restrictions. Market share threshold The Guidelines recognise that R&D are only likely to give rise to restrictive effects on competition where the parties have market power on the existing markets and/or competition with respect to innovation is appreciably reduced. There is no absolute threshold above which it can be presumed that an R&D agreement creates or maintains market power. However, if the parties are actual or realistic potential competitors, they will be able to benefit from the safe harbour of the R&D Block Exemption if, at the time the agreement was entered into, their combined market share did not exceed 25% of the relevant market for the products capable of being improved or replaced by the contract products. Commission Regulation (EU) 1217/2010, art 4(2) If the parties to the agreement are not actual or (realistic) potential competitors, they can benefit from the R&D Block Exemption regardless of their market share. Commission Regulation (EU) 1217/2010, art 4(1) Type of agreement The agreement must fall into one of the following six categories to benefit from exemption: Commission Regulation (EU) 1217/2010, arts 1(1)(a) and 2(1) pure R&D, that is, involving the joint R&D of contract products or contract technologies, but excluding the joint exploitation of the results of that R&D involving both joint R&D and the joint exploitation of the results of that R&D ( exploitation of the results means the production or distribution of the contract products, the application of the contract technologies, the assignment or licensing of intellectual property rights, or the communication of knowhow required for such manufacture or application) involving the joint exploitation of the results of joint R&D carried out pursuant to a prior agreement between the same parties involving both paid-for R&D and the joint exploitation of the results of that paid-for R&D ( paid-for R&D means R&D that is carried out by one party and financed by a financing party) involving the joint exploitation of the results of paid-for R&D carried out pursuant to a prior agreement between the same parties; or involving only paid-for R&D, excluding the joint exploitation of the results of that R&D. Conditions for exemption The agreement must meet the following conditions: Commission Regulation (EU) 1217/2010, art 3

The agreement must stipulate that all the parties have full access to the final results of the joint R&D, including any resulting intellectual property rights and knowhow, for the purposes of further R&D and exploitation, as soon as they become available (However, where the parties limit their rights of exploitation, access to the results for the purposes of exploitation may be limited accordingly.). If compensation for access to the results (for the purposes of further R&D or exploitation) is agreed, it must not be so high as to effectively impede such access. Where the agreement provides only for joint R&D, it must stipulate that each party must be granted access to any pre-existing knowhow of the other parties, if this knowhow is indispensable for the purposes of its exploitation of the results. If compensation is agreed for giving access to pre-existing knowhow, it must not be so high as to effectively impede such access. Any joint exploitation may only pertain to results which are protected by intellectual property rights or constitute knowhow and which are indispensable for the manufacture of the contract products or the application of the contract technologies. If the parties have allocated between them individual tasks or imposed restrictions upon each other regarding the exploitation of the results, and one party has been charged with the manufacture of the products, that party must be required to fulfil orders for supplies of the products from the other parties, except where the R&D agreement also provides for joint distribution or the parties have agreed that only the party manufacturing the contract products may distribute them. No hardcore restrictions The agreement must also not contain any so-called hardcore restrictions. These are restrictions that are considered so obviously anti-competitive as to be presumed to be caught by the Article 101(1) TFEU prohibition, regardless of the parties market shares. They include: Commission Regulation (EU) 1217/2010, art 5 Non-compete restrictions limiting the freedom of the parties to carry out R&D independently or in cooperation with third parties in a field unconnected with that to which the R&D agreement in question relates or, after the completion of the joint R&D or the paid-for R&D, in the field to which it relates or in a connected field. Quantitative restrictions on output or sales, subject to very limited exceptions (including production targets or sales targets under certain circumstances, restrictions where the parties have allocated between them individual tasks such as production or distribution, or imposed restrictions upon each other regarding the exploitation of the results, or restrictions on the freedom to market or sell products which compete with the contract products during the contract period). The fixing of prices (or elements of pricing) when selling the contract product or licensing the contract technologies to third parties, with the exception of: the fixing of prices charged to immediate customers, where the joint exploitation of the results includes the joint distribution of the contract products; or the fixing of licence fees charged to immediate licensees, where the joint exploitation of the results includes the joint licensing of the contract technologies Restrictions on passive sales by the parties to certain territories or customers in the EEA, although a requirement to exclusively license the results to another party is not prohibited. Restrictions on active sales by the parties to certain territories or customers in the EEA which have not been exclusively allocated to one of the parties under permitted specialisation in the context of exploitation arrangements (ie where tasks have been allocated between the parties). Restrictions limiting parallel trade, including: a requirement to refuse to meet demand from customers in the parties respective territories, or from customers otherwise allocated between the parties by way of specialisation in the context of exploitation, who would market the contract products in other territories within the EEA; or a requirement to make it difficult for users or resellers to obtain the contract products from other resellers within the EEA An agreement that contains any of the above hardcore restrictions will be void and unenforceable in its entirety. Excluded restrictions If the agreement contains any of the following restrictions, they will be unenforceable (however the rest of the agreement will not necessarily be unenforceable): No challenge obligations which prohibit either party from challenging: after completion of the R&D, the validity of the parties intellectual property rights which are relevant to the R&D, or after the expiry of the R&D agreement, the validity of the parties intellectual property rights which protect the results of the R&D, although the agreement may provide for the possibility of termination if one of the parties challenges the validity of such intellectual property rights. Licensing restrictions which prohibit either party from granting licences to third parties to manufacture the contract products or to apply the contract technologies, unless the agreement provides for the exploitation of the results of the R&D by at least one of the parties and such exploitation takes place in the EEA vis-à-vis third parties.

Duration of safe harbour protection Provided that the market share threshold is not met and the conditions discussed above are fulfilled, the parties can rely on an exemption under the R&D Block Exemption for the entire duration of the joint R&D stage. Where the R&D agreement extends to joint exploitation, the parties can continue to rely on the R&D Block Exemption for an initial seven-year period from the date the contract products are first put on the market in the EU. Following that seven-year period, the exemption will only be available for as long as the parties combined market share does not exceed 25% of the relevant market for the contract products within the EEA. Application of specific assessment criteria under horizontal guidelines In cases where an R&D agreement does not benefit from the R&D Block Exemption, an individual analysis is required, taking into account the assessment factors identified in the Guidelines. Restrictions of competition by object The Guidelines explain that an R&D agreement will restrict competition by object if it does not truly concern joint R&D, but serves as a tool to engage in a disguised cartel, that is, prohibited price-fixing, output limitation or market allocation. EU horizontal guidelines, para 128 An agreement containing any of these hardcore restrictions will be automatically void and unenforceable. Restrictive effects on competition The Guidelines lay out the following guiding principles: EU horizontal guidelines, para 135 Market power-if an agreement falls outside the R&D Block Exemption because the parties combined market share exceeds 25%, it will not necessarily give rise to restrictive effects on competition. However, the stronger the parties combined position on existing markets and/or the more competition in innovation is restricted, the more likely it is that the R&D agreement can cause restrictive effects on competition. Nature of parties competitive relationship-the Guidelines clarify that the competitive relationship between the parties needs to be analysed in the context of affected existing markets and/ or innovation, and potential competition between them needs to be realistic. The decisive question is whether each party independently has the necessary means as regards assets, knowhow and other resources to carry out the R&D If, objectively, the answer is no, the R&D agreement will normally not have any restrictive effects on competition. This could apply, for instance, where the parties bring together complementary skills or resources. EU horizontal guidelines, para 130 Similarly, where R&D is outsourced to an entity that is not active in the exploitation of the results (such as a specialised company, research institute or academic body), restrictive effects are unlikely due to the complementary nature of the cooperating parties. EU horizontal guidelines, para 131 Nature and scope of cooperation-generally a distinction should be drawn between pure R&D and providing for more comprehensive cooperation involving different stages of the exploitation of results (that is, licensing, production or marketing). Pure R&D which only involve joint R&D but not the joint exploitation of possible results, will rarely give rise to restrictive effects on competition. These will generally only be problematic if competition with respect to innovation may be appreciably reduced, thus leaving only a limited number of credible competing R&D poles (in other words, R&D efforts directed towards a certain new product or technology, and the substitutes for that). EU horizontal guidelines, para 132 By contrast, an agreement involving joint production and/or marketing of a product or technology gives rise to greater risks of restrictive effects (such as higher prices or reduced output, quality or variety) on the existing market. EU horizontal guidelines, para 137 Regard should also be had to the possible impact on neighbouring markets. Where, for example, the agreement concerns R&D relating to an input for a final product, factors such as the importance of that input in the final product should form part of the assessment. EU horizontal guidelines, para 136 If the R&D is directed at an entirely new product or technology and thus creates its own entirely new market, restrictive effects such as higher prices on existing markets are considered unlikely. However, in these cases, the analysis needs to focus on possible restrictions of innovation such as on quality and variety of possible future products or technologies or the speed of innovation. Key factors to consider would be whether other competitors would still have access to key inputs or technologies (such as by way of a licence). EU horizontal guidelines, para 139 Many R&D may have effects on both existing markets and innovation. For example, if significant competitors on an existing technology-market cooperate to develop a new technology which may one day replace the existing technology, their relationship may slow down the development of the new

technology if they have market power on the existing market and a strong position with respect to R&D. Therefore, where both existing and potential future markets may be affected, both need to be assessed having regard to the parties market positions, the number of market players or innovators, entry conditions and so on. EU horizontal guidelines, para 139 Assessment under Article 101(3) TFEU If an agreement is found to be restrictive of competition within the meaning of Article 101(1) TFEU, it is necessary to determine whether it produces any pro-competitive benefits and to assess whether those pro-competitive benefits outweigh the restrictive effects on competition. Art 101(1) TFEU The balancing of restrictive and pro-competitive effects is conducted exclusively within the framework laid down by Article 101(3) TFEU. If the pro-competitive effects do not outweigh a restriction of competition, Article 101(2) TFEU stipulates that the agreement shall be automatically void. Art 101(3) TFEU Art 101(2) TFEU For the general principles as to how to assess an agreement under Article 101(3) TFEU, see further, Competition issues impacting horizontal commercial. With respect to the specific principles applicable to R&D, the Guidelines provide the following: any restrictions on competition must be indispensable-ie not go beyond what is necessary to achieve the efficiency gains generated by the R&D agreement EU horizontal guidelines, para 142 efficiency gains must be passed on to consumers to an extent that it outweighs the restrictive effects on competition. For example, the introduction of an improved product must outweigh any price increases or other restrictive effects. The Guidelines indicate that, generally speaking, it is more likely that an R&D agreement will bring about efficiency gains that benefit consumers if the R&D agreement results in the combination of complementary skills and assets EU horizontal guidelines, para 142 the criteria of Article 101(3) TFEU cannot be met if the parties are afforded the possibility of eliminating competition in respect of a substantial part of the products (or technologies) in question EU horizontal guidelines, para 144 The Guidelines also detail in what context (in terms of timing) this assessment should be carried out, including how the European Commission would be likely to apply Article 101(3) TFEU to particular exclusivity provisions imposed to guard against risks such as sunk investments in a project. See further, Individual Exemptions under Article 101(3) TFEU and Applying Article 101(3) TFEU-case study. R&D can be very beneficial for consumers and markets, as well as the parties concerned. However, an R&D agreement (or material parts of it) found to be restrictive of competition within the meaning of Article 101(1) TFEU, which is, or are not saved, by Article 101(3) TFEU, will be automatically void and unenforceable. Reed Elsevier (UK) Limited trading as LexisNexis. Registered office 1-3 Strand London WC2N 5JR Registered in England number 2746621 VAT Registered No. GB 730 8595 20. LexisNexis and the Knowledge Burst logo are trademarks of Reed Elsevier Properties Inc. LexisNexis 2015 0815-015. The information in this document is current as of August 2015 and is subject to change without notice.