The valuation of patent rights sounds like a simple enough concept. It is true that

Similar documents
Patents as Indicators

Outline. Patents as indicators. Economic research on patents. What are patent citations? Two types of data. Measuring the returns to innovation (2)

BOSTON UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF LAW

Intellectual Property Research: Encouraging Debate and Informing Decisions

How Patent Damages Skew Licensing Markets

A Citation-Based Patent Evaluation Framework to Reveal Hidden Value and Enable Strategic Business Decisions

Using patent data as indicators. Prof. Bronwyn H. Hall University of California at Berkeley, University of Maastricht; NBER, NIESR, and IFS

The effect of patent protection on the timing of alliance entry

Patent Statistics as an Innovation Indicator Lecture 3.1

Patent Data Project - NSF Proposal Iain Cockburn, Bronwyn H. Hall, Woody Powell, and Manuel Trajtenberg February 2005

Patent Analysis in External Technology Acquisition: A Case of Taiwan Semiconductor Manufacturing Company

The influence of the amount of inventors on patent quality

Patents, R&D-Performing Sectors, and the Technology Spillover Effect

Prepared for BCLT IP and Entrepreneurship Symposium Boalt Hall March, 2008 Scott Stern, Northwestern and NBER

HOW TO READ A PATENT. To Understand a Patent, It is Essential to be able to Read a Patent. ATIP Law 2014, All Rights Reserved.

Patent Due Diligence

USING AHP ON PATENT VALUATION

The Objective Valuation of Non-Traded IP. Jonathan D. Putnam

Slide 25 Advantages and disadvantages of patenting

New Emphasis on the Analytical Approach of Apportionment In Determination of a Reasonable Royalty

Patents: Who uses them, for what and what are they worth?

"Competition Policy and Intellectual Property Rights in the Republic of Latvia since 1991" (the working title)

Patent Mining: Use of Data/Text Mining for Supporting Patent Retrieval and Analysis

from Patent Reassignments

Revisiting the USPTO Concordance Between the U.S. Patent Classification and the Standard Industrial Classification Systems

Protect your ideas. An introduction to patents for students of natural sciences, engineering, medicine and business administration

Hitotsubashi University. Institute of Innovation Research. Tokyo, Japan

Slide 15 The "social contract" implicit in the patent system

Standard-Essential Patents

INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY (IP) SME SCOREBOARD 2016

INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY (IP) SME SCOREBOARD 2016

THE MARKET VALUE OF TECHNOLOGICAL INNOVATION; EVIDENCE FROM EUROPEAN PATENTS

Are large firms withdrawing from investing in science?

The role of Intellectual Property (IP) in R&D-based companies: Setting the context of the relative importance and Management of IP

Patents and Clean Energy Technologies in Africa

Do inventors value secrecy in patenting? Evidence from the American Inventor s Protection Act of 1999

Complementarity, Fragmentation and the Effects of Patent Thicket

The Dynamics of the Transfer and Renewal of Patents

Introduction Disclose at Your Own Risk! Prior Art Searching - Patents

Chapter 8. Technology and Growth

MR. SCOTT A. BARNES, CPA, CFF, CGMA

Cognitive Distances in Prior Art Search by the Triadic Patent Offices: Empirical Evidence from International Search Reports

Public Hearings Concerning the Evolving Intellectual Property Marketplace

Social returns to direct private innovation support: the patent system

Issues and Possible Reforms in the U.S. Patent System

25 The Choice of Forms in Licensing Agreements: Case Study of the Petrochemical Industry

Patents and innovation (and competition) Bronwyn H. Hall UC Berkeley, U of Maastricht, NBER, and IFS London

DO RESEARCH AND DEVELOPMENT CONSORTIA INCREASE PATENT VALUE? THE CASE OF SEMATECH

SCIENTIFIC RESEARCH AND INNOVATION - DECISIVE FACTORS OF BUSINESS PERFORMANCE

Where do patent measures fall short in the life sciences? Bhaven N. Sampat Columbia University and NBER July 28, 2017

DEFENSIVE PUBLICATION IN FRANCE

Patent Valuation with Forecasts of Forward Citations. by Nathan Falk Claremont McKenna College and Kenneth Train University of California, Berkeley

More of the same or something different? Technological originality and novelty in public procurement-related patents

Citations, Family Size, Opposition and the Value of Patent Rights

Potential of Actuarial Approach for Patent Matters with some topics on Recent Increase of Patent Valuation Needs in Japan -

Assessing the socioeconomic. public R&D. A review on the state of the art, and current work at the OECD. Beñat Bilbao-Osorio Paris, 11 June 2008

Why do Inventors Reference Papers and Patents in their Patent Applications?

WIPO REGIONAL SEMINAR ON SUPPORT SERVICES FOR INVENTORS, VALUATION AND COMMERCIALIZATION OF INVENTIONS AND RESEARCH RESULTS

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE MEANING OF PATENT CITATIONS: REPORT ON THE NBER/CASE-WESTERN RESERVE SURVEY OF PATENTEES

Business Method Patents, Innovation, and Policy. Bronwyn H. Hall UC Berkeley and NBER

Patenting Strategies. The First Steps. Patenting Strategies / Bernhard Nussbaumer, 12/17/2009 1

The Economics of Innovation

PROTECTING INVENTIONS: THE ROLE OF PATENTS, UTILITY MODELS AND DESIGNS

University IP and Technology Management. University IP and Technology Management

executives are often viewed to better understand the merits of scientific over commercial solutions.

20 Bounded Rationality and Related Concepts Fundamental to Intellectual Property Analysis

Green policies, clean technology spillovers and growth Antoine Dechezleprêtre London School of Economics

Fast-tracking green patent applications: An empirical analysis. Antoine Dechezleprêtre

An Estimation of Knowledge Production Function By Industry in Korea 1

Macchine e capitale (elementi introduttivi)

CHANGES IN UNIVERSITY PATENT QUALITY AFTER THE BAYH-DOLE ACT: A RE-EXAMINATION *

CS 4984 Software Patents

The Impact of the Breadth of Patent Protection and the Japanese University Patents

Effects of early patent disclosure on knowledge dissemination: evidence from the pre-grant publication system introduced in the United States

Licensing or Not Licensing?:

Which Patent Systems Are Better For Inventors?

To be presented at Fifth Annual Conference on Innovation and Entrepreneurship, Northwestern University, Friday, June 15, 2012

WPI Intellectual Property A day in the life of the tech transfer office. Todd Keiller Director, Intellectual Property and Innovation

Incentive System for Inventors

Market Value and Patent Citations

Innovation and Firm Value: An Investigation of the Changing Role of Patents and Firm Publications

Building a Competitive Edge: Protecting Inventions by Patents and Utility Models

Quantifying Changes in Innovation: Patenting Activity and IPR Regimes *

The Value of Knowledge Spillovers

Litigation Funding for Patent Disputes

MEASURING INNOVATION PERFORMANCE

California State University, Northridge Policy Statement on Inventions and Patents

Standards as a knowledge source for R&D: A first look at their characteristics based on inventor survey and patent bibliographic data

ty of solutions to the societal needs and problems. This perspective links the knowledge-base of the society with its problem-suite and may help

7 The Trends of Applications for Industrial Property Rights in Japan

Technological Forecasting & Social Change

POLICY ON INVENTIONS AND SOFTWARE

UNIVERSITIES AND TECHNOLOGY TRANSFER PATENT ATTORNEYS TRADE MARK ATTORNEYS

Coase 2.0 and the Patent System Why Policy Makers Need To Focus on the Information Sharing Incentives and Mechanisms in Patent Law.

A POLICY in REGARDS to INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY. OCTOBER UNIVERSITY for MODERN SCIENCES and ARTS (MSA)

HOW TO COUNT PATENTS AND VALUE INTELLECTUAL PR0PERTY:THE USES OF PATENT RENEWAL AND APPLICATION DATA*

LEFIC WORKING PAPER Improving Patent Valuation Methods for Management. Validating New Indicators by Understanding Patenting Strategies

IP and Technology Management for Universities

Software Patent Citations: A Consistent Weighted Ranking

Shell Project Delivery Best Practices Dick L. Wynberg, GM NOV Projects Integrated Gas Shell Global Solutions International B.V

Transcription:

Page 1 The valuation of patent rights sounds like a simple enough concept. It is true that agents routinely appraise and trade individual patents. But small-sample methods (generally derived from basic accounting and finance) are often crude, and their results may bear little relationship to economic fundamentals, especially in litigation. On the other hand, large-sample methods usually lack much invention-specific data on which to condition value estimates. Regardless of sample size, proper valuation methods require both conceptual delineation and empirical ingenuity. Concepts. Legally, a patent is the right to exclude others from making, using or selling an invention. In economic terms, that right is an asset, yielding a non-negative returns stream while it is enforceable. Because the right is a private means (increased exclusivity) to a public end (increased productivity), a patent s private value only partially conveys its market significance. Unlike most property rights, patents do not comprise the affirmative right to use the invention. Absent the right to use, patents may generate private value only when combined with complementary assets, such as a license under other patents. Contracting problems (e.g. asymmetric information) may strongly influence value. A patent may generate private returns apart from the right to exclude rivals. The patentee may use it: to monitor employee performance; to signal otherwise unobservable quality to prospective financiers; to enhance reputation; to signal a willingness to litigate; or to reduce the costs of settlement in the event that litigation occurs ( defensive patenting ). In large samples, it is usually impossible either to observe the magnitude and timing of these sources of value, or to decompose them.

Page 2 Patents also impose unobservable private costs on the patentee. Chiefly, the inventor must disclose the means for reproducing the invention. Disclosure reduces the cost to rivals of reproducing the invention (static spillover) and conducting R&D (dynamic spillover). Apart from reducing the incentive to invent, these private costs imply social benefits not captured by the patentee. Cross-sectionally, patents are usually modeled as having a one-dimensional quality (which is either synonymous with, or a monotone function of, the patent s value). More precisely, a patent s private value depends significantly on the exclusivity conferred by its claims, but its uncaptured social value depends significantly on the scope of its disclosure (which must be at least as broad as the claims). For various reasons, including rival use of the patentee s disclosure to develop competing innovations ( creative destruction ), the social and private values of a patent may diverge. Thus, it is theoretically preferable, but empirically much less tractable, to model patents as having two-dimensional quality. Over time, because of ongoing research by the patentee and his rivals, the private returns to patent protection may fluctuate sharply up or down, in response to complementary or competitive discoveries. The variance is likely to be larger in a patent s early years. Stylized facts. The following stylized facts bear on the calculation of aggregate private patent values: 1. Whether aggregated by firm, industry or country, patent counts do not vary much from one period to the next.

Page 3 2. The distribution of patent values is skewed. 3. Social and private patent values are imperfectly correlated. 4. Ex ante and ex post values are imperfectly correlated. 5. Most patents are not traded. 6. Samples are selected (not all innovations are patented; not all applications are filed in any single country; not all applications are granted). Related research Proceeding in the direction of generally increasing complexity and structure, the following categories describe large-sample models that economists have developed to value patent rights. Lanjouw, Pakes and Putnam (1998) surveys recent papers. Patent counts. A variety of models employ simple patent counts to indicate the value of patent rights. Strictly speaking, patent counts indicate quantities, rather than values. Under certain assumptions, relative quantities may be proportional to relative values. For example, if two patent samples are drawn from the same value distribution, then the ratio of quantities is an efficient estimator of the ratio of values. Griliches (1990) reviews a large number of studies that, implicitly or explicitly, rely on this assumption. Griliches view of patent [counts] as economic indicators is not encouraging ( The food here is terrible. Yes, and the portions are so small. ). Stylized facts #1 and #2 combine to thwart inference. A firm facing a fixed budget constraint may patent its best N inventions, which implies little intertemporal variation in patent counts even if their realized quality varies markedly. Thus, patent counts are a biased measure of value. Because R&D outcomes are highly variable and skewed, patent

Page 4 counts are an imprecise measure of value. For these reasons, the assumption that patent samples are drawn from the same distribution is difficult to test, and often false. (On the other hand, fixed budget constraints for R&D and patenting imply that patent counts may proxy for the value of R&D inputs. Hausman, Hall and Griliches (1986) model the lag relationship between patent counts and R&D, and find an approximately contemporaneous relationship.) One may compute implied patent values by associating patent counts with other observable aggregates. On the macro level, McCalman (2005) employs the structural imitation model of Eaton and Kortum (1996) to determine international trade in patents. He estimates that the worldwide value of patent applications filed by U.S. inventors in 1988 was about $12.4 billion ($163,700 per application). The estimates for four other large patenting countries vary: France, $147,200; Germany, $82,200; U.K., $53,100; Japan, $47,700. At the firm level, Pakes (1985) constructs a time series model of patent applications, R&D and the stock market rate of return. Controlling for R&D expenditures, an unanticipated patent application implies an $800,000 increase in market capitalization. (This relatively high value also reflects investors revised expectations of research success, and the selection of publicly traded patentees (which are larger and more successful than average). Patent citations (weighted patent counts). Patent examiners cite prior patents when they decide whether to grant a patent application. Analysts count these citations to

Page 5 indicate the value of the cited patent. Patent counts are then weighted by the number of citations. A recent book-length treatment is Jaffe and Trajtenberg (eds.) (2002). This branch of the literature divides in two: estimates of the relationship between citations and patent value; and studies that assume that relationship. In the former category, Trajtenberg s (1990) pioneering study showed that citation-weighted patent counts perform better than unweighted counts in explaining aggregate patent value (see Harhoff et al. 2003). However, this and subsequent studies found that citations tend to indicate the social value of the patent, rather than the purely private value (stylized fact #3). Private value is better captured by self-citations from the patentee s own later inventions. Hall et al. (2005) show that weighted patent counts are associated with and predict higher stock market returns. Assuming that citations proxy for value, Henderson, Jaffe and Trajtenberg (1998) examine the contribution of university patenting to commercial technology; Trajtenberg, Henderson and Jaffe (1997) find that the basicness of university patents relative to corporate patents has narrowed over time. Jaffe, Trajtenberg and Henderson (1993) model the spatial distribution of dynamic spillovers. Other indicator-based methods. Lanjouw and Schankerman (2004) construct a composite index of patent quality using several indicators (forward- and backwardcitations, number of claims, and number of filing countries). This combination of ex ante and ex post measures (stylized fact #4) efficiently aggregates informationally distinct components of patent value. The composite also explains related ex post decisions (e.g.,

Page 6 patent renewal and litigation); forward citations (an ex post measure) demonstrate the greatest explanatory power. Structural models: patent renewals and patent applications. Although most patents are not traded (stylized fact #5), patent office rules effectively require patentees to make optimal investments to create and maintain patent rights. These investments reveal information about the expected value of the asset. The information is censored, however, because (conditional on choosing to invest) patentees make the same investment regardless of the expected value. Structural econometric models identify the underlying value distribution. Most countries require that a patentee pay an increasing fee to keep a patent right in force. Beginning with Pakes and Schankerman (1984), so-called patent renewal models exploit the optimal stopping problem implicit in the annual investment decision. The ex post value distribution is identified from the shares of an annual cohort that are renewed each subsequent year when patentees confront known renewal fee schedules, observed over multiple cohorts. In relatively simple deterministic models (Schankerman and Pakes 1986; Sullivan 1994; Schankerman 1998), returns are assumed to depreciate at a known rate following an initial draw from the value distribution. In more complex options models (Pakes 1986; Lanjouw 1998), returns evolve stochastically. In both models, the average patent value is relatively low (for example, less than $20,000 in Europe during the post-war period). Lorenz plots reveal that the top 10% of patents account for about 47% of the total value distribution.

Page 7 The value distribution may also be identified from cross-sectional information (Putnam 1996). Under international rules, patent applicants typically determine simultaneously whether to file in each jurisdiction outside their home jurisdiction. Applicants file if the capitalized value of net returns exceeds the application cost. Application models capture filing anywhere in the world, conditional on a common information set, which mitigates both intertemporal (stylized fact #4) and sample selection (stylized fact #6) problems. The ex ante value distribution is identified from the combination of filing countries, assuming that national returns are the product of a common invention-level random effect and an idiosyncratic national market draw. Putnam (1996) values the mean German patent at about $69,000 in 1974, with the top 10% of patents accounting for about 70% of the value distribution. Small-sample methods Small-sample patent valuation typically occurs in a legal or quasi-legal context, such as licensing or litigation. In infringement litigation, the law typically allows one of three measures of damages: the patentee s lost profits; the infringer s incremental profits; or a reasonable royalty (conceived as the outcome of a hypothetical licensing negotiation (Weil et al. 2001)). Typically, parties employ discounted cash flow methods and comparable license transactions to support valuation claims. Both ex ante and ex post methods are used, not always consistently. The law also allows limited consideration of an infringer s ex ante alternatives to infringement, such as inventing a substitute. Generally, the most difficult legal and empirical question is: What fraction of (actual or expected) profits should be imputed to the patent? While much damages

Page 8 jurisprudence remains economically ad hoc, courts are increasingly inclined to require the same market analyses that characterize antitrust law (Crystal Semiconductor v. TriTech Microelectronics, 246 F. 3d 1336, (Fed. Cir. 2001)). References Eaton, J., and S. Kortum. 1996. Trade in Ideas: Patenting and Productivity in the OECD. Journal of International Economics 40: 251 78. Griliches, Z. 1990. Patent Statistics as Economic Indicators: A Survey. Journal of Economic Literature: 1661-1707. Hall, B., A. Jaffe and M. Trajtenberg. 2005. Market Value and Patent Citations. Rand Journal of Economics 36: 16-38. Harhoff, D., F. Narin, F. M. Scherer and K. Vopel. 1999. Citation Frequency and the Value of Patented Inventions. Review of Economics and Statistics 81(3): 511-515. Hausman, J., B. Hall and Z. Griliches. 1986. Patents and R&D: Is There a Lag? International Economic Review 27: 265-83. Henderson, R., A. Jaffe and M. Trajtenberg. 1998. Universities as a Source of Commercial Technology: A Detailed Analysis of University Patenting, 1965-1988. Review of Economics and Statistics 80(1): 119-127. Jaffe, A., M. Trajtenberg and R. Henderson. 1993. Geographic Localization of Knowledge Spillovers as Evidenced by Patent Citations. Quarterly Journal of Economics 43(4): 578-598. Jaffe, A. and M. Trajtenberg. 2002. Patents, Citations and Innovations: A Window on the Knowledge Economy. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press. Lanjouw, J. O. 1998. Patent Protection in the Shadow of Infringement: Simulation Estimations of Patent Value. Review of Economic Studies 65: 671-710. Lanjouw, J. O. and M. Schankerman. 2004. Patent Quality and Research Productivity: Measuring Innovation with Multiple Indicators. The Economic Journal 114: 441-65.

Page 9 Lanjouw, J.O., Pakes, A. and Putnam, J. 1998. How to Count Patents and Value Intellectual Property: Uses of Patent Renewal and Application Data. Journal of Industrial Economics 46(4): 405-433. McCalman, P. 2005. Who Enjoys TRIPs Abroad? An Empirical Analysis of Intellectual Property Rights in the Uruguay Round. Canadian Journal of Economics: 574-603. Pakes, A. 1986. Patents as Options: Some Estimates of the Value of Holding European Patent Stocks. Econometrica 54: 755-784. Pakes, A. and M. Schankerman. 1984. The Rate of Obsolescence of Patents, Research Gestation Lags, and the Private Rate of Return to Research Resources. In Z. Griliches (ed.), R&D, Patents and Productivity. NBER Conference Series. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press. Pakes, A. and M. Simpson. 1989. Patent Renewal Data. Brookings Papers: Microeconomics: 331-410. Putnam, J. 1996. The Value of International Patent Rights. Ph.D. Thesis. Yale University. Schankerman, M. and A. Pakes. 1986. Estimates of the Value of Patent Rights in European Countries during the Post-1950 Period. Economic Journal 96: 1052-1076. Schankerman, M. 1998. How Valuable is Patent Protection? Estimates by Technology Field. Rand Journal of Economics 29(1): 77-107. Sullivan, R. 1994. Estimates of the Value of Patent Rights in Great Britain and Ireland, 1852-1876. Economica 61: 37-58. Trajtenberg, M. 1990. A Penny for Your Quotes: Patent Citations and the Value of Innovation. Rand Journal of Economics 21(1): 172-187. Trajtenberg, M., R. Henderson and A. Jaffe. 1997. University versus Corporate Patents: A Window on the Basicness of Invention. Economics of Innovation and New Technology 5(1): 19-50. Weil, R. L., M. J. Wagner and P. B. Frank. 2001. Litigation Services Handbook: The Role of the Financial Expert. New York: Wiley.