Examining the Link Between U.S. Employment Growth and Tech Investment

Similar documents
U.S. Employment Growth and Tech Investment: A New Link

Long-run trend, Business Cycle & Short-run shocks in real GDP

Procedia - Social and Behavioral Sciences 195 ( 2015 ) World Conference on Technology, Innovation and Entrepreneurship

INNOVATION AND ECONOMIC GROWTH CASE STUDY CHINA AFTER THE WTO

The drivers of productivity dynamics over the last 15 years 1

Post Keynesian Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Theory: How to retain the IS-LM model and still sleep at night.

Analysis of Economic Data

How do we know macroeconomic time series are stationary?

DETERMINANTS OF STATE ECONOMIC GROWTH: COMPLEMENTARY RELATIONSHIPS BETWEEN R&D AND HUMAN CAPITAL

THE U.S. SEMICONDUCTOR INDUSTRY:

The Impact of Technological Change within the Home

Taking the Measure of St. Louis

COMPETITIVNESS, INNOVATION AND GROWTH: THE CASE OF MACEDONIA

CURRICULUM VITAE Economist, Domestic Research Function, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, New York, NY

Web Appendix: Online Reputation Mechanisms and the Decreasing Value of Chain Affiliation

Unit 1: The Economic Fundamentals Weeks How does scarcity impact the decisions individuals and societies must make?

Appendices. Chile models. Appendix

An Empirical Look at Software Patents (Working Paper )

GARY D. HANSEN 4/17/2018. Address:

The (Un)Reliability of Real-Time Output Gap Estimates with Revised Data

Government of Puerto Rico Department of Labor and Human Resources Bureau of Labor Statistics BUSINESS EMPLOYMENT DYNAMICS: FOURTH QUARTER

The Relationship Between Annual GDP Growth and Income Inequality: Developed and Undeveloped Countries

Advanced information on the Bank of Sweden Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 11 October 2004

Dr. Jeffrey Michael. Executive Director, Center for Business and Policy Research University of the Pacific

Capital Planning Retreat Economic Outlook Alan E. Maguire

BUSINESS EMPLOYMENT DYNAMICS THIRD QUARTER

NATHAN S. BALKE Professor. ADDRESS: Department of Economics OFFICE PHONE: (214)

Research on the Influencing Factors of the. Adoption of BIM Technology

BUSINESS EMPLOYMENT DYNAMICS

The CTA Consumer Sentiment Indexes

How U.S. Employment Is Changing

Analysis of the influence of external environmental factors on the development of high-tech enterprises

Advanced Econometrics and Statistics

Technology Innovations: Powering or Pummeling the Economy?

Yi Wen Assistant Vice President

Manifold s Methodology for Updating Population Estimates and Projections

Curriculum Vitae November Karen K. Lewis

Macroeconomic Theory 2

Department of Economics Working Paper

THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN PRIVATE EQUITY AND ECONOMIC GROWTH

The Weakness of the Gini Coefficient in Farm States

Research on the Impact of R&D Investment on Firm Performance in China's Internet of Things Industry

The most recent advancement of endogenous growth theory has been the emergence

The CTA Consumer Sentiment Indexes

The Economic Census and Its Role in Economic Statistics

Appendix to Report Patenting Prosperity: Invention and Economic Performance in the United States and its Metropolitan Areas

PETER N. IRELAND. Department of Economics Boston College 140 Commonwealth Avenue Chestnut Hill, MA

Internet Appendix for. Industry Expertise of Independent Directors and Board Monitoring

HOW DOES INCOME DISTRIBUTION AFFECT ECONOMIC GROWTH? EVIDENCE FROM JAPANESE PREFECTURAL DATA

THE EVOLUTION OF TECHNOLOGY DIFFUSION AND THE GREAT DIVERGENCE

Modelling Non-Stationary Time Series

SEMICONDUCTOR INDUSTRY ASSOCIATION FACTBOOK

GEORGE RATIU Director, Quantitative & Commercial Research National Association of REALTORS

DOES INFORMATION AND COMMUNICATION TECHNOLOGY DEVELOPMENT CONTRIBUTES TO ECONOMIC GROWTH?

Unified Growth Theory

Life Science Journal 2014;11(5s)

Real-time Forecast Combinations for the Oil Price

I Economic Growth 5. Second Edition. Robert J. Barro Xavier Sala-i-Martin. The MIT Press Cambridge, Massachusetts London, England

The Relative Performance of Conditional Volatility Models

Detrending and the Distributional Properties of U.S. Output Time Series

The Changing Structure of Africa s Economies

Volume 29, Issue 4. Detrending and the Distributional Properties of U.S. Output Time Series

Size of California s economy US$ trillions, 2009

Real-time output gaps in the estimation of Taylor rules: A red herring? Christopher Adam* and David Cobham** December 2004

An Analysis of Participation in Bird Watching in the United States

from Patent Reassignments

VENTURE CAPITAL INVESTING REACHES HIGHEST LEVEL SINCE Q WITH $13.0 BILLION INVESTED DURING Q2 2014, ACCORDING TO THE MONEYTREE REPORT

SAN DIEGO S QUARTERLY ECONOMIC SNAPSHOT

Technology and Competitiveness in Vietnam

3Q13. Trends in Terms of Venture Financings in Silicon Valley. Third Quarter Fenwick. fenwick & west llp

NEWS RELEASE FOR WIRE TRANSMISSION: 8:30 A.M. EDT, FRIDAY, APRIL 17, William Zeile: (202) BEA 09-14

Trends in Terms of Venture Financings In Silicon Valley (Second Quarter 2011)

DETERMINATES OF CLUSTERING ACROSS AMERICA S NATIONAL PARKS: AN APPLICATION OF THE GINI COEFFICIENT

PRIOR APPOINTMENTS Assistant Professor, University of Michigan, Department of Economics,

Missouri Economic Indicator Brief: Manufacturing Industries

THE ECONOMIC OUTLOOK FOR THE U.S. AND THE CONSTRUCTION INDUSTRY

IXIA S PUBLIC ART SURVEY 2013 SUMMARY AND KEY FINDINGS. Published February 2014

Curriculum Vitae July 11, 2012 PETER RUPERT

1Q04 Update: Silicon Demand Will Move to a Full Recovery

Measuring Romania s Creative Economy

Using Administrative Records for Imputation in the Decennial Census 1

Real Estate Trends and Outlook

Macroeconomics: Principles, Applications, and Tools

18 The Impact of Revisions of the Patent System on Innovation in the Pharmaceutical Industry (*)

April Keywords: Imitation; Innovation; R&D-based growth model JEL classification: O32; O40

Silicon Valley Venture Capital Survey Second Quarter 2018

The percentage of Series A rounds declined significantly, to 12% of all deals.

Winter 2004/05. Shaping Oklahoma s Future Economy. Success Stories: SemGroup, SolArc Technology Yearbook

QUARTERLY REVIEW OF ACADEMIC LITERATURE ON THE ECONOMICS OF RESEARCH AND INNOVATION

Export variety, technological content and economic performance: The case of Portugal

Economic Clusters Efficiency Mathematical Evaluation

The Great Recession, Entrepreneurship, and Productivity Performance

The CTA Consumer Sentiment Indexes

2012 ACCE Industry Advisory Board Best Practices Positioning Your Firm After the Great Recession

Construction of SARIMAXmodels

Profitability, Long Waves and the Recurrence of General Crises

Demand for Commitment in Online Gaming: A Large-Scale Field Experiment

Research Methodologies for Management Sciences & Interdisciplinary Research in Contemporary World

State of the Glass Container Industry

Do different types of capital flows respond to the same fundamentals and in the same degree? Recent evidence for EMs

Transcription:

Examining the Link Between U.S. Employment Growth and Tech Investment Rajeev Dhawan and Harold Vásquez-Ruíz Economic Forecasting Center J. Mack Robinson College of Business Georgia State University August 2, 2011 Abstract This paper finds a statistically valid link from confidence indexes CEO, Consumer Confidence and Michigan Sentiment to both investment growth in technology equipment and software (henceforth tech investment) and subsequent job growth in the U.S. employment data for the last 50 years. Our regression analysis allows us to look for factors that can explain the slow pace of job recovery experienced in the last three recessions. Specifically, we identify tech investment as an important determinant of employment growth, and we identify CEO confidence index as the causal factor for tech investment via the durable goods orders since the late 80 s. This result stands even when we substituted the CEO index with either Michigan sentiment or consumer confidence index that are longer time series which capture more economic expansions and contractions. Thus, a jobless recovery is a facet of a low of confidence level in the economy that affects tech investment, with a good barometer of this investment being orders for durable goods. Keywords: Employment Growth, CEO Confidence, Technology Investment, Consumer Sentiment, Granger Causality JEL Classification: C41, D21, E31 We thank Mohammad Ashraf, Leon Goldstein, Karsten Jeske, Pedro Silos, Neven Valev and participants at the 2010 Western Economic Association s International Meeting for their helpful comments and discussion. A previous version of this paper was circulated under the title U.S. Employment Growth and Tech Investment: A New Link. All errors are our responsibility. For comments, please contact Rajeev Dhawan at rdhawan@gsu.edu or Harold Vásquez-Ruíz at hav@gsu.edu

1 Introduction & Motivation When compared to recoveries from recessions in the United States before the 90 s, the 1990-91 and 2001 recoveries were initially jobless and took longer for the economy approximately three and four years, respectively to reach the pre-recession peak employment level. The recovery from the 2007-2009 recession again appears to be weak in terms of job growth by historical standards. 1 This paper uses time-series methods to look for factors that can explain this delay in job recovery after the last three recessions. Specifically, we identify that investment in technology equipment and software (henceforth referred as tech investment) have been an important determinant of employment growth since 1959. This result confers with the fact that the basic building block of any type of macromodel for an economy is the investment equation, whether it is the Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) modeling framework or the reduced form structural modeling. 2 Figure 1 illustrates the quarterly U.S. nonfarm employment (EMP), tech investment (TECH), and total investment in equipment and software (ES-TECH), all series in natural logs, from 1959 to 2011Q1. 3 As the graph suggest, total investment series lead the cycles of expansion and contraction of the employment series by up to two quarters. For instance, in the 1969-70 recession, investment reached its peak in 1969Q3, while the employment series achieved its maximum in 1969Q4. Additionally, in the recession from 1980Q1 to 1980Q3, investment and employment reached their peaks in 1979Q3 and 1980Q1, respectively. 1 The National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) has declared the recession that started in December of 2007 to be over in June of 2009. However, nonfarm employment series, a critical component of dating business cycles, seems to have bottomed out only in February 2010, but the unemployment rate has dropped significantly below its October 2009 peak value of 10.1%. However, job creation from March 2010 to June 2011 has averaged about 105,300 per month. At this rate it will take another six years to reach the pre-recession peak employment level. Sinai (2010) discusses the challenges in conceptualizing and dating the business cycle in a changing economy in detail. 2 The paper by Cooley and Prescott (1995) lays out the building blocks of a DSGE model with Greenwood, Hercowitz and Krusell (1997) extension to two types of capital. The book by Klein and Goldberger (1955) discusses in detail the formation of a reduced form macromodel. 3 The difference between the ES-TECH and TECH series is that the ES-TECH series does not only include technology equipment but also all types of equipments. Please, refer to the data section for more details. 2

A similar phenomenon also occurs in the 1981-82, 1990-91, 2001, and the 2007-2009 recessions. 4 Furthermore, the tech investment series seems to show more comovement with employment in the last three recessions when the recoveries were jobless. Figure 2 shows the 5-year (20 quarters) moving correlation of employment and tech investment series, which is particularly strong for most of the sample period. 5 We employ a multi-step investigative procedure in this paper. We first check for the long-term co-movement (or cointegration) of employment and tech investment series, then we look at their predictive power using the Granger s test. We did not find cointegration between employment and tech investment or strong evidence that tech investment Granger-causes employment. Nevertheless, as Granger causality tests only check for precedence of one series before the other and not causality as it is usually understood, we ran standard regressions to quantify the impact of investment on employment. Our regression estimates indicate that a 1% permanent jump in the growth rate of tech investment raises the employment growth rate by 0.02%. Thus, a $10 billion increase in tech investment produces an extra 84,400 jobs in the economy. This number rises to 242,300 when we use the bigger measure of investment that includes all types of equipment investment. 6 Next, we looked for factors that impact tech investment and identified confidence indexes Conference Board s (CBO) Consumer Confidence index, CEO Confidence index, and University of Michigan s Consumer Sentiment index as the causal factor for tech investment growth. This investigative line is motivated by the long tradition in macroeconomics (from Pigou (1927), Keynes (1936) to the survey of Benhabib and Farmer (1999)) that suggests that changes in expectations may be an important driver for business cycles. 4 See NBER website (http://www.nber.org/cycles.html) for reference dates on business cycle expansions and contractions. 5 Tech investment as a proportion of total investment in equipment and software was less than 20% until mid-80 s. It started to rise afterwards and then with the advent of internet and computer usage in mid-90 s it rose to be above 50% of the total investment. This break point of mid-80 s is also evident in the productivity figures and its implications for Okun s law as analyzed by Gordon (2010). 6 The permanent increase is obtained by adding up the significant coefficients of the dependent variable in the chosen specification. This is different from a impact propensity coefficient, which measures the contemporary change t in the dependent variable, which in this case is the coefficient on dlog(tech) t (see Wooldridge, 2003, p. 27). Also, all calculations here and later in the text are done at the sample averages for the variables in question. 3

For example, the paper by Beaudry and Portier (2004) shows how recessions and booms arise in a general equilibrium structure due to difficulties encountered by economic agents in properly forecasting the economy s future needs for capital resulting in investment errors. For example, the work of Jaimovich and Rebelo (2007) shows that confidence can affect future economic performance when economic agents overreact to emergence of new innovations by being either too optimistic or pessimistic. 7 We found that CEO confidence Granger-causes tech investment in the short term (one to two quarter lag), but tech investment can help to predict the movements in the CEO confidence index at higher lags (three and four quarter lags). The regression estimates show that a 1% increase in the CEO confidence index raises the growth rate of tech investment by almost 0.034%. 8 As the CEO confidence index series only starts in 1988, we also utilized the University of Michigan s consumer sentiment series that starts in 1960 and the Conference Board s consumer confidence index that starts in 1977Q3. The regression results are very similar when we substituted these series for the CEO index. The Granger test shows that causality runs from the Michigan sentiment index to tech investment in the short term (one quarter lag), but there is double-causality between these series from two up to four lags, at very high significance levels. Also, our regressions show that a one percent permanent increase in the Michigan sentiment index raises the growth rate of tech investment by approximately 0.12%. This effect remains unchanged, at 0.116%, when we restrict the sample estimation to 1986 onwards. Furthermore for the bigger definition of investment this coefficient is 0.32%. On the other hand, the Granger test identifies only one direction of causality from the CBO s consumer confidence to the tech investment series, and we estimated that one percent permanent increase in the confidence index raises the growth rate of tech investment also by approximately 0.142%. To put more structure to this causal relationship, we looked at advance orders for durable goods that are highly correlated with tech investment, and found that the CEO 7 Leduc (2010) discusses the implications for monetary authorities when changes in confidence affect business cycle fluctuations. 8 For the bigger measure of investment the CEO confidence raises investment by 0.056%. 4

confidence index Granger-causes durable goods orders up to four quarter lags. The regression results indicate that a 1% increase in the CEO confidence index raises the growth rate of durable goods orders by 0.13%. The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the data series used and their sources. Section 3 presents the time series analysis starting with testing for stationarity, undertaking cointegration analysis and Granger causality tests and then performing the regression analysis in section 4. Section 5 presents the concluding remarks. 2 The Data Our analysis relies on quarterly data from the last five decades on nonresidential investment in technology equipment and software (TECH), nonresidential investment in all types of equipment and software (ES-TECH), CEO Confidence index (CEO), Michigan consumer sentiment index (MICHIGAN), consumer confidence index (CONFIDENCE), employment (EMP), and new orders for manufactured durable goods (ORDERS). The economic data and its sources are described as following. TECH, or tech investment, is constructed by adding up the series of investment in computer equipment, software, communications equipment, and other information processing equipment produced by the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA). We use quarterly data from 1959Q1 to 2011Q1, measured in billions of 2005 dollars. The ES-TECH series is a broad category of investment that measures the real nonresidential investment in equipment and software. The measure for EMP is total nonfarm payroll, in thousand, from 1959Q1 to 2011Q1. This series is obtained from Current Employment Statistics (CES) program of the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics Department. 9 We also defined a subcategory of employment called private employment (PRIVEMP) that subtracts government employment from the total number. The private share of employment was approximately 82.7% of the total employment in 2010. 9 Details of this survey and the rest of the variables used in this study are in a separate appendix, which is available upon request. 5

The quarterly CEO confidence index, from the Conference Board, is constructed from a survey of 800 chief executives of corporations in the United States. The index value ranges between 0 and 100 based on their level of optimism, and the data series starts in 1988Q1. The appendix contains the details about the construction methodology of this index. As this series is shorter than the EMP and TECH series, we also utilized Michigan s consumer sentiment survey that starts in 1960Q1 and the Conference Board consumer confidence index that starts in 1977Q3 henceforth referred as MICHIGAN and CONFIDENCE, respectively to substitute for the CEO confidence index as part of our sensitivity analysis. 10 The ORDERS series measures the dollar value of new orders or intent to buy supported by a strong commitment from the buyer of manufacturers producing durable goods. The series is obtained at monthly frequency from the U.S. Census Bureau (data construction and survey details are available by request). To make the ORDERS series consistent with all our data, we converted this series to quarterly frequency by adding up the months, then we proceed to seasonally adjust the data before doing our statistical analysis. 11 3 Time series analysis 3.1 Unit Root Tests Table 1 shows the results of the Augmented Dickey-Fuller and the Phillip-Perron tests (henceforth ADF and PP, respectively) on the EMP, PRIVEMP, TECH, ES-TECH, OR- 10 The Michigan consumer sentiment index is a monthly survey so we converted it to quarterly frequency by averaging the monthly values in each quarter. This index is positively correlated with the CEO confidence index, however the correlation coefficient changed considerably depending on the years chosen for its calculation. For instance, from 1988Q1 to 2011Q1, the correlation between MICHIGAN and CEO is 0.03. However, the correlation is highly positive at 0.53 from 2001Q1 to 2011Q1. The correlation between CEO and CONFIDENCE is small and negative, at -0.14, for the whole sample period, but this correlation increases to 0.26 when we restrict the sample from 2001Q1 onwards. Finally, the correlation between MICHIGAN and CONFERENCE is highly positive at 0.83 for the 1977Q3 to 2011Q1 period and 0.90 from 2001Q1 onwards. 11 Durable goods are those with an expected life of at least three years. For the analysis, besides the ORDERS series, we also obtained information on manufacturer s new orders for capital goods. Our results remain consistent when we subtract from both series the component of defense equipment. 6

DERS, and our three confidence indexes measures: CEO, MICHIGAN, and CONFI- DENCE. To test the null hypothesis of unit root, we include the 1%, 5%, and 10% tests critical values. Panels 1 and 2 present the tests results for the log-levels of the series, log( ), while panels 3 and 4 show the first difference of the log of the series, dlog( ). We included a trend and a constant term for the series in log-levels and only a constant term for the series in first differences during the estimations. The results of the ADF and PP tests suggest that we cannot reject the unit root hypothesis for EMP, PRIVEMP, TECH, ES-TECH, and ORDERS at the standard confidence levels. For the confidence index series, the results of the ADP and PP tests are slightly different. Both the ADF and the PP tests on the CEO confidence index indicate that we can reject the unit root hypothesis therefore this series is stationary. However, for the MICHIGAN series the ADF and PP tests reject the unit root hypothesis only at 10% confidence level, indicating a weak evidence of nonstationarity. Finally, both the ADF and PP tests do not reject the unit root hypothesis for the CONFIDENCE series, hence the CONFIDENCE series is nonstationary. 12 3.2 Cointegration and Causality Tests We concluded in the previous section that the CEO series is stationary, but the rest of the series EMP, PRIVEMP, TECH, ES-TECH, ORDERS, MICHIGAN, and CONFIDENCE are nonstationary. Now, we proceed to investigate if there is a linear combination among our nonstationary time series that make them stationary. For this purpose, we use the Johansen s test to evaluate the cointegration hypothesis. This cointegration test is important because it will allow us to rule out a priori any spurious relationships in the series. Table 2 presents the results of the Johansen s cointegration test for TECH with EMP, PRIVEMP, CONFIDENCE, MICHIGAN, and ORDERS; MICHIGAN with EMP, PRIVEMP, and ORDERS. We also test for cointegration between ORDERS and CON- 12 The difference in the critical values for the tests applied to the CEO, MICHIGAN, and CONFIDENCE series is due to the difference in their sample sizes. 7

FIDENCE series. The table shows only one cointegration relationship, which relates the CONFIDENCE index series with the TECH series. For the rest of the variables, the Johansen s test rejected the null hypothesis of at most 1 cointegration equation in favor of no cointegration equations. 13 Table 3 shows the Granger causality test on TECH with EMP, CEO, MICHIGAN, and CONFIDENCE series. The first panel identifies only one direction of causality from EMP to TECH when testing from one up to four lags. Panel 2 shows that causality runs only from CEO to TECH at one and two lags, but then the direction of causality is only from TECH to CEO at higher lags (three and four lags). The third panel of this table shows the Granger causality test between TECH and MICHIGAN confidence index. At one lag, we find that only the MICHIGAN index Granger causes the TECH series. However, from two up to four lags, the test suggest a double causality at high significance levels. The bottom panel shows the Granger test between TECH and CONFIDENCE series. In this case, we cannot reject the null of no causality from TECH to CONFIDENCE, but we do reject this hypothesis from CONFIDENCE to TECH at one lag. That is, we found only one direction of causality that runs from CONFIDENCE to TECH, from one up to four lags. 14 In table 4, we present the Granger test between the ORDERS series and the three confidence indexes: CEO, MICHIGAN, and CONFIDENCE. Looking at the top panel, at one lag, the test shows that only the CEO confidence index precedes, or Granger-cause, the ORDERS series at 1% confidence level, but from two up to four lags there is a double causality relationship between ORDERS and CEO. The same results are obtained when 13 We also ran the Johansen s test subtituting ES-TECH for TECH and the results were almost the same but the only cointegration relationship found relates ES-TECH with MICHIGAN index series. 14 We also run the Granger causality test between ES-TECH and EMP, CEO, MICHIGAN, and CON- FIDENCE. We find a double causality between ES-TECH and EMP at one lag. However, when testing from two up to four lags this relationship runs in one direction, from EMP to ES-TECH. When testing causality with the CEO series, we find one direction of causality from CEO to ES-TECH at one and four lags, but a double causality between ES-TECH and CEO when using two and three lags. For the MICHIGAN index, from one up to four lags, the test suggests a double-causality with the ES-TECH series at high significance levels. For the CONFIDENCE series, causality runs only in one direction from CONFIDENCE to ES-TECH, at all lags, and a very high significance level. 8

testing for Granger-causality between the ORDERS series and the MICHIGAN confidence index series (see panel two) we comment about the causality relationships between alternative measures of durable goods and capital goods orders and the MICHIGAN index in the next footnote. The bottom panel shows evidence of a Granger-causality only from CONFIDENCE to ORDERS at one lag. However, the test suggests a double causality relationship between ORDERS and CONFIDENCE from two up to four lags. The previous results hold when using the ORDERS series without the defense equipment component, and the new orders for capital goods, with and without defense equipments as well. 15 4 Regression analysis In this section, we test for the hypothesis that confidence indexes are an important determinant for tech investment, which also significantly explain the employment growth rate in the U.S. economy. Our procedure consists of evaluating the statistical significance and economic magnitude of these relationships in a set of ordinary least squares regressions. The results are presented in tables 5 to 11. Table 5 shows the regression of the growth rate of employment, dlog(emp), on the growth rate of tech, dlog(tech), and the growth rate of the real gross domestic product, dlog(gdpr). 16 The adjusted R-square, R 2, suggest that our model explains between 83% and 89% of the growth rate of total nonfarm employment, and the impact propensity coefficient on tech investment is significant at 1% level, across all specifications. Looking at specifications 1 to 4, the immediate change on the growth rate of employment due to a one unit increase in the growth rate of tech investment is about 0.02%. The coefficients on 15 We find different results in the Granger causality test between the MICHIGAN index and our alternative measures of durable goods and capital goods orders. For instance, when we used the ORDERS series without the capital defense equipment component, we did not find a causality relationship at one lag. However, the Granger test found a double-causality from two up to four lags. For the total new orders for capital goods, there is no causality in any direction at one lag either. However, the causality runs only in one direction from MICHIGAN to the total new orders for capital goods when we tested for two up to four lags. For capital goods orders with no defense equipments, the test shows that causality runs only in one direction at all lags, from the MICHIGAN consumer sentiment index. 16 We subtract the TECH component from the total GDP measure. This variable is included to capture business cycle fluctuations. 9

the three lagged values of tech investment are not significant at standard confidence levels. In specification 5, we restricted the sample from 1986Q1 onwards and the magnitude of the coefficient in the TECH variable remains unchanged. However, the impact propensity coefficient on the GDPr variable drops considerably. Specification 5 indicates that a permanent increase in GDPr raises the growth rate of employment by 0.31%. When we consider the investment in equipment and software (ES-TECH), a broader category than TECH, as the dependent variable, the coefficient value raises to about 0.08% see specification 6. We identified the CEO confidence index as the leading factor that might explain the growth rate of tech investment from Granger causality testing in the previous section. In table 6 we run a regression of the growth rate of tech investment, dlog(tech), on the log value of CEO index, log(ceo). The impact propensity coefficient on CEO index is statistically insignificant at all standard confidence levels. However, the lagged CEO variable is significant at 10% confidence level and it also explains 19% of the growth rate of TECH (see specification 4). Looking at the regression in column 4, where we use only the lagged CEO variable, we estimated that a one percent increase in the CEO confidence index causes the growth rate of tech investment to rise by 0.034%. 17 In Table 7, we regress growth rate of ORDERS on the CEO confidence index. Regression in column 2 shows that the impact propensity coefficient of log(ceo) is highly significant, at all standard confidence levels and explains about 31% of the growth rate of ORDERS. Regressions in column 3 and 4 show that the coefficients for lagged variables are also significant. Thus, we ran another regression with only one lagged value of the CEO index, and the coefficient for this variable was highly significant at a 1% confidence level. Specification 5 indicates that a one percentage increase in the CEO index causes approximately a 0.14% change in the growth rate of new orders for manufactured durable goods. Hence, the rise in the CEO index not only explains the changes in the growth 17 We also substitute the CEO Confidence index for the CBO s Business Executive Confidence index as part of our sensitivity analysis, and the estimated coefficient was positive and significant (0.025%) at a 1% confidence level. 10

rate of tech investment, but also it predicts the changes in the growth rate of manufactured durable goods orders an important determinant for tech investment which we will demonstrate in the next set of regressions. In table 8 we identify the channel through which the CEO confidence index affects the tech investment series: the total manufactured durable goods orders, ORDERS. Our regressions show the strong positive and significant relationship between the durable goods orders and the TECH series. Column 1 shows that an immediate change in the growth rate of ORDERS increases the growth rate of TECH by about 0.20%. These estimates are highly significant, at the 1% level, and the regressions explains 23% of the growth rate in TECH. The coefficients on the lagged values of ORDERS are insignificant at all standard confidence levels. The small sample size of the CEO confidence index (from 1988 onwards) only allows us to examine three recession episodes at the most. To check for the significance and magnitude over a longer time horizon we substituted the CEO index with the MICHI- GAN (1960 onwards) and CONFIDENCE (1977 onwards) indexes. Tables 9 and 10 show the regressions of the growth rate of TECH on the growth rate of the MICHIGAN and CONFIDENCE series. As we expected, both the MICHIGAN and CONFIDENCE have a strong positive and significant relationship with the TECH series. Table 9 shows that the MICHIGAN confidence index significantly explains the TECH series at one and two lags. However, the explanatory power of these estimations is considerably low. Columns 2 to 4, suggest that a one percent permanent increase in the MICHIGAN confidence index raises the growth rate of TECH approximately 0.12%. Also, this economic magnitude remains unchanged (at 0.116%) when we restrict the sample in the tech series from 1986 onwards (column 5). In specification 6, we replace the investment in equipment and software series (ES-TECH) for the tech series, and all the estimated coefficients are now significant at 1% and 5% confidence levels. The explanatory power of the model also increased substantially from 20% (column 5) to 31% (column 6). This specification suggests that 11

a one percent permanent increase in the growth rate of the MICHIGAN index rises the growth rate of TECH by 0.317%. Table 10 shows that the contemporaneous change in the CONFIDENCE index significantly explains the growth rate of TECH, at 1% significance level. The effect of CONFIDENCE on TECH also increases when we consider lagged values of the CONFIDENCE series. Specifically, a one percent permanent increase in the CONFIDENCE index series raises the growth rate of TECH by 0.142% (column 3). Using the broad definition of investment (ES-TECH), the estimate increases considerably to 0.256% (column 6). We also tested if the MICHIGAN and CONFIDENCE indexes might be good explanatory variables for the growth rate of new order for manufactured goods, and the results are shown in table 11. As we can observe, in column 3, only the first lag of the MICHI- GAN series is significant, at a 5% level, but the R 2 suggest that there is still a great deal of explanatory power in this regression (24%). The regression in column 6 shows that the growth rate in the CONFIDENCE index also significantly affect the growth rate of ORDERS up to one lag, at all standard significance levels. According to this estimation, a one percent permanent increase in the growth rate of CONFIDENCE causes the growth rate of ORDERS to raise about 0.263%. 12

5 Conclusion The empirical analysis of this paper shows that tech investment is an important determinant for job growth in the U.S. economy. Also, our analysis suggests that tech investment increases when the CEO s perceptions about the future of the U.S. economy improve, and this result is consistent when we substituted the CEO index by the MICHIGAN and the CONFIDENCE indexes in our senstivity analysis. Finally, the rise in CEO s confidence is reflected in the increasing amount of new orders for manufactured durable goods which is highly correlated with tech investment. Thus, the diagram below sums up the analysis where confidence measures impact tech ivestment via the durable goods channel leading to employment changes. Thus, a lack of confidence is responsible for the jobless recovery we are experiencing at present. Employment growth mechanism in the U.S. economy. 13

But this begs the question of what economic factors confidence measures capture or symbolize? Do they capture meaningful independent information about the economy or just repackage information captured in other economic indicators? Ludvigson (2004) examined this issue in relation to what impact CONFIDENCE has on consumer spending, and found the impact to be muted for future path of consumer spending, thus confirms results of previous studies like Carroll, Fuhrer and Wilcox (1994) and Bram and Ludvigson (1998). Additionally, Mishkin (1978) found that although the MICHIGAN index reflected consumers perceptions of the probability of financial distress or liquidity problems, accounting for balance sheet variables made the index less useful for predicting expenditures on consumer durables. 18 On the other hand, Matsusaka and Sbordone (1995), find that a causal relation exists between the MICHIGAN index and GDP growth. The question of whether confidence measures react to a host of economic developments or contribute to them is a challenging issue to sort out empirically. Previous research has analyzed the impact of confidence indexes on variables that are a final product (consumption or GDP) of past investment decisions. However, our work focuses on the building block for economic growth (proxied by employment change), which is investment. Thus, our findings should be read as that the confidence indexes play a critical role in determining investment levels, which is a causal component in employment growth. These indexes may either capture financial distress or liquidity issues, future productivity changes, or coordination of agents beliefs that do not otherwise show up in econometricians information sets. For future research it will be interesting to see how these competing hypotheses explain the movement in different confidence measures which in turn impacts investment. 18 Fuhrer (1993) finds that 70 percent of the MICHIGAN index volatility can be explained by variation in national income, the unemployment rate, inflation and real interest rates. 14

References [1] Beaudry, P. and F. Portier (2007). When can changes in expectations cause business cycle fluctuations in neo-classical settings? Economic Theory 135(1), pp. 458-477. Journal of [2] Benhabib, J. and R. Farmer (1999). Indeterminacy and Sunspots in Macroeconomics. In J. Talor and M. Woodford (Eds.), Handbook of Macroeconomics, vol. 1A, pp. 387-448. New York: North-Holland. [3] Bram, J. and Sydney C. Ludvigson (1998, June). Does Consumer Confidence Forecast Household Expenditure? A Sentiment Index Horse Race. Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Economic Policy Review 4(2), pp. 59-78. [4] Carroll, C. D., Jeffrey C. Fuhrer, and David W. Wilcox (1994). Does Consumer Sentiment Forecast Household Spending? If So Why? American Economic Review 84(5), pp. 1397-408. [5] Cooley, Thomas F. and Edward C. Prescott (1995). Economic Growth and Business Cycles. In Thomas F. Cooley (Ed.), Frontiers of Business Cycle Research, Chapter 1, 99. pp. 1-38. New Jersey: Princeton University Press. [6] Fuhrer, J. C. (1993,January-February). What Role Does Consumer Sentiment Play in the U.S. Macroeconomy? New England Economic Review, pp. 32-44. [7] Gordon, R. J. (2010). Okun s Law and Productivity Innovations. American Economic Review, 100(2), pp. 11-15. 15

[8] Greenwood, J., Zvi Hercowitz, and Per Krusell (1997). Long-Run Implications of Investment-Specific Technological Change. The American Economic Review 87(3), pp. 342-62. [9] Hamilton, J. D. (1994). Time Series Analysis (1st ed.). Princeton University Press. [10] Jaimovich, N. and S. Rebelo (2007, April). Behavioral Theories of the Business Cycle. Journal of the European Economic Association, pp. 361-368. [11] Keynes, J. (1936). The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. London: Macmillan. [12] Klein, L. R. and A. S. Goldberger (1955). Econometric Model of the United States, 1929-52. Amsterdam: North-Holland. [13] Leduc, S. (2010, November). Confidence and the Business Cycle. Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, Economic Letter 2010-35. [14] Matsusaka, J. G. and Argia M. Sbordone (1995). Consumer Confidence and Economic Fluctuations. Economic Enquiry 33(2), pp. 296-318. [15] Mishkin, F. S. (1978). Consumer Sentiment and Spending on Durable Goods. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1, pp. 217-32. [16] Pigou, A. (1926). Industrial Fluctuations. London: MacMillan. [17] Sinai, A. (2010). The Business Cycle in a Changing Economy: Conceptualization, Measurement, Dating. American Economic Review 100(2), pp. 25-29. [18] Sydney C. L. (2004, Spring). Consumer Confidence and Consumer Spending. Journal of Economic Perspectives 18(2), pp. 29-50. 16

[19] The Conference Board (2009). CEO Confidence Index From 1988Q1 to 2009Q3 [statistics]. Available from IHS Global Insight database. [20] The Conference Board (2009). Consumer Confidence Index From 1977Q1 to 2009Q3 [statistics]. Available from IHS Global Insight database. [21] University of MICHIGAN (2009). MICHIGAN Consumer Confidence Index From 1960Q1 to 2009Q3 [statistics]. Available from IHS Global Insight database. [22] U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis (2009). Investment in Technology Equipment and Software From 1959Q1 to 2009Q3 [statistics]. Available from IHS Global Insight database. [23] U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics (2009). Total Nonfarm Employment and Total Nonfarm Private Employment From 1959Q1 to 2009Q3 [statistics]. Available from IHS Global Insight database. [24] U.S. Census Bureau (2009). Manufacturer Durable Goods Orders From 1992Q2 to 2009Q3 [statistics]. Available from IHS Global Insight database. [25] Wooldridge, J. M. (2003). Introductory Econometrics: A Modern Approach (2nd ed.). Thomson, South-Western. 17

12.0 8 11.8 6 11.6 11.4 Last recession: 2007Q4-2009Q2 4 11.2 2 11.0 10.8 EM P, left TECH, right ES-TECH, right 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 0 Figure 1: U.S. nonfarm employment and tech investment, 1959Q1 to 2011Q1. All series in logs. 18

Correlations.5 0.5 1 EMP & Tech EMP & ES TECH 1960q1 1970q1 1980q1 1990q1 2000q1 2010q1 Time in quarters Figure 2: Moving Correlation of EMP, TECH, and ES-TECH. Period from 1959Q1 to 2011Q1. All series in log differences from the trend, which is computed using a Hodrick-Prescott filter. 19

Table 1: Nonstationarity Tests: Augmented Dickey-Fuller(ADF) & Phillip-Perron (PP) 1 Variable tested ADF test PP test 1% c.v. 5% c.v. 10% c.v. EMP, PRIVEMP, TECH & ORDERS: in levels 2 log(emp) 2.238 0.342-4.004-3.436-3.136 log(privemp) 2.169 0.143 log(tech) 0.155-0.246 log(es-tech) -1.530-2.480 log(orders) -1.658-2.117-4.095-3.475-3.165 CEO, MICHIGAN & CONFIDENCE: in levels 3 log(ceo) -4.234-4.183-4.058-3.458-3.155 log(michigan) -3.197-3.289-4.005-3.436-3.136 log(confidence) -2.394-2.597-4.029-3.445-3.145 EMP, PRIVEMP, TECH & ORDERS: in first differences dlog(emp) -4.860-5.199-3.474-2.883-2.573 dlog(priv) -5.100-5.478 dlog(tech) -10.840-11.176 dlog(es-tech) -8.858-9.086 dlog(orders) 4-5.401-5.457-3.546-2.911-2.590 CEO, MICHIGAN & CONFIDENCE: in first differences dlog(ceo) -11.518-12.044-3.523-2.897-2.584 dlog(michigan) -16.128-16.062-3.476-2.883-2.573 dlog(confidence) -10.897-12.820-3.499-2.888-2.578 1 The null hypothesis is that the series has a unit root. For the series in log-levels (log), we use a constant and a linear trend assumption. For the series in first differences of the log (dlog), we only employ a constant term in the estimations. 2 The sample for EMP, PRIVEMP, and TECH series is from 1959Q1 to 2011Q1. The sample for ORDERS series is from 1992Q2 to 2011Q1. 3 The sample for CEO is 1988Q1-2011Q1, for MICHIGAN 1960Q1-2011Q1, and for CONFIDENCE is 1977Q3-2011Q1. 4 We also ran the ADF and PP tests for the manufactured durable goods orders without the defense equipment component, as well as for the total new orders for capital goods, including both defense and nondefense components. All results indicate that we cannot reject the unit root hypothesis for these series. 20

Table 2: Johansen s test for cointegration Series 1 Max. Rank Hypothesis Trace stat. 2 Decision 3 EMP & TECH 0 No cointegration 14.4031* Accepted 1 Cointegration 6.8050 Rejected PRIVEMP & TECH 0 No cointegration 20.2152 Rejected 1 Cointegration 8.4538 Rejected CONFIDENCE & TECH 0 No cointegration 21.6312 Rejected 1 Cointegration 6.5568* Accepted CONFIDENCE & EMP 0 No cointegration 13.7557* Accepted 1 Cointegration 2.4776 Rejected CONFIDENCE & PRIVEMP 0 No cointegration 12.8140* Accepted 1 Cointegration 2.8026 Rejected MICHIGAN & TECH 0 No cointegration 16.2844* Accepted 1 Cointegration 7.0705 Rejected MICHIGAN & EMP 0 No cointegration 12.5916* Accepted 1 Cointegration 2.9761 Rejected MICHIGAN & PRIVEMP 0 No cointegration 10.7688* Accepted 1 Cointegration 2.4153 Rejected CONFIDENCE & ORDERS 0 No cointegration 12.7585* Accepted 1 Cointegration 1.7921 Rejected MICHIGAN & ORDERS 0 No cointegration 16.0420* Accepted 1 Cointegration 3.1763 Rejected TECH & ORDERS 4 0 No cointegration 12.6638* Accepted 1 Cointegration 2.3872 Rejected 1 All series are in log-levels. For EMP, PRIV, and TECH the sample is from 1959Q3-2011Q1. For MICHIGAN, CONFIDENCE, and ORDERS the sample start at 1960Q1, 1976Q2, and 1992Q2, respectively. 2 The * indicates the number of cointegrating equations selected. 3 For Max. Rank= 0 the 5% and 1% critical values are 15.41 and 20.04, respectively. For Max. Rank= 1 the 5% and 1% critical values are 3.76 and 6.65, respectively 4 We also ran the Johansen s test between TECH and the manufactured durable goods and capital goods orders with and without the defense equipment component, and we accepted the null of No cointegration in all cases. 21

Table 3: Pairwise Granger Causality Test: TECH with EMP, CEO, MICHIGAN, and CONFIDENCE Null Hypothesis 1 Lags F-Stat. Prob. Decision 2 dlog(tech) & dlog(emp); period: 1959Q1-2011Q1 dlog(tech) does not cause dlog(emp) 1 1.3190 0.2521 DNR dlog(emp) does not cause dlog(tech) 1 21.718 0.0000 R. 1% dlog(tech) does not cause dlog(emp) 2 1.2485 0.2892 DNR dlog(emp) does not cause dlog(tech) 2 5.9408 0.0031 R. 1% dlog(tech) does not cause dlog(emp) 3 0.9644 0.4106 DNR dlog(emp) does not cause dlog(tech) 3 5.9503 0.0007 R. 1% dlog(tech) does not cause dlog(emp) 4 0.5456 0.7025 DNR dlog(emp) does not cause dlog(tech) 4 5.5166 0.0003 R. 1% dlog(tech) & log(ceo); period: 1988Q1-2011Q1 log(ceo) does not cause dlog(tech) 1 3.5526 0.0627 R. 10% dlog(tech) does not cause log(ceo) 1 0.8155 0.3689 DNR log(ceo) does not cause dlog(tech) 2 2.9599 0.0571 R. 10% dlog(tech) does not cause log(ceo) 2 1.1610 0.3180 DNR log(ceo) does not cause dlog(tech) 3 2.0332 0.1155 DNR dlog(tech) does not cause log(ceo) 3 3.0879 0.0316 R. 5% log(ceo) does not cause dlog(tech) 4 1.4759 0.2173 DNR dlog(tech) does not cause log(ceo) 4 2.4598 0.0520 R. 5% dlog(tech) & dlog(michigan); period: 1960Q1-2011Q1 dlog(michigan) does not cause dlog(tech) 1 3.9647 0.0478 R. 5% dlog(tech) does not cause dlog(michigan) 1 0.3901 0.5329 DNR dlog(michigan) does not cause dlog(tech) 2 4.6753 0.0104 R. 1% dlog(tech) does not cause dlog(michigan) 2 3.2633 0.0403 R. 5% dlog(michigan) does not cause dlog(tech) 3 3.0215 0.0309 R. 5% dlog(tech) does not cause dlog(michigan) 3 2.3003 0.0786 R. 10% dlog(michigan) does not cause dlog(tech) 4 2.3887 0.0524 R. 5% dlog(tech) does not cause dlog(michigan) 4 2.4458 0.0479 R. 5% dlog(tech) & dlog(confidence); period: 1977Q3-2011Q1 dlog(confidence) does not cause dlog(tech) 1 5.2934 0.0230 R. 5% dlog(tech) does not cause dlog(confidence) 1 0.5408 0.4634 DNR dlog(confidence) does not cause dlog(tech) 2 4.1752 0.0175 R. 5% dlog(tech) does not cause dlog(confidence) 2 0.8062 0.4488 DNR dlog(confidence) does not cause dlog(tech) 3 2.7438 0.0460 R. 5% dlog(tech) does not cause dlog(confidence) 3 0.8947 0.4460 DNR dlog(confidence) does not cause dlog(tech) 4 2.1516 0.0785 R. 10% dlog(tech) does not cause dlog(confidence) 4 0.6965 0.5958 DNR 1 Causality is defined in the sense of Granger. 2 R = reject at 1%, 5%, or 10% confidence level. DNR = do not reject. A rejection means presence of Granger causality. 22

Table 4: Pairwise Granger Causality Test: ORDERS with CEO, MICHIGAN, and CON- FIDENCE. Sample from 1992Q2 to 2011Q1. Null Hypothesis 1 Lags F-Stat. Prob. Decision 2 dlog(orders) & log(ceo) dlog(orders) does not cause log(ceo) 1 0.1614 0.6891 DNR log(ceo) does not cause dlog(orders) 1 16.204 0.0001 R. 1% dlog(orders) does not cause log(ceo) 2 5.7395 0.0050 R. 1% log(ceo) does not cause dlog(orders) 2 7.8463 0.0009 R. 1% dlog(orders) does not cause log(ceo) 3 6.0008 0.0011 R. 1% log(ceo) does not cause dlog(orders) 3 5.0239 0.0034 R. 1% dlog(orders) does not cause log(ceo) 4 4.6687 0.0023 R. 1% log(ceo) does not cause dlog(orders) 4 3.6641 0.0096 R. 1% dlog(orders) & dlog(michiganigan) dlog(orders) does not cause dlog(michigan) 1 0.0012 0.9730 DNR dlog(michigan) does not cause dlog(orders) 1 5.8479 0.0182 R. 5% dlog(orders) does not cause dlog(michigan) 2 3.6103 0.0323 R. 5% dlog(michigan) does not cause dlog(orders) 2 3.4991 0.0358 R. 5% dlog(orders) does not cause dlog(michigan) 3 2.9166 0.0407 R. 5% dlog(michigan) does not cause dlog(orders) 3 6.1436 0.0010 R. 1% dlog(orders) does not cause dlog(michigan) 4 2.0214 0.1024 R. 10% dlog(michigan) does not cause dlog(orders) 4 4.9118 0.0017 R. 1% dlog(orders) & dlog(confidence) dlog(orders) does not cause dlog(confidence) 1 0.7858 0.3784 DNR dlog(confidence) does not cause dlog(orders) 1 7.8730 0.0065 R. 1% dlog(orders) does not cause dlog(confidence) 2 4.7061 0.0122 R. 5% dlog(confidence) does not cause dlog(orders) 2 4.6733 0.0125 R. 5% dlog(orders) does not cause dlog(confidence) 3 5.6925 0.0016 R. 1% dlog(confidence) does not cause dlog(orders) 3 8.4167 0.0001 R. 1% dlog(orders) does not cause dlog(confidence) 4 3.9544 0.0064 R. 1% dlog(confidence) does not cause dlog(orders) 4 6.7221 0.0001 R. 1% 1 Causality is defined in the sense of Granger. 2 R = reject at 1%, 5%, or 10% confidence level. DNR = do not reject. A rejection means presence of Granger causality. 23

Table 5: Dependent Variable: dlog(emp) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) 1 (6) dlog(emp) t 1 0.620*** 0.590*** 0.578*** 0.502*** 0.614*** 0.643*** (0.039) (0.046) (0.048) (0.061) (0.060) (0.056) dlog(tech) t 0.021*** 0.021*** 0.021*** 0.021*** 0.021*** (0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.006) (0.008) dlog(gdpr) t 0.284*** 0.281*** 0.270*** 0.278*** 0.180*** (0.023) (0.024) (0.023) (0.023) (0.031) dlog(tech) t 1 0.003 0.002 0.002 0.008 (0.007) (0.007) (0.007) (0.009) dlog(gdpr) t 1 0.027 0.038 0.057** 0.128*** (0.026) (0.025) (0.026) (0.037) dlog(tech) t 2 0-0.003 0.006 (0.007) (0.007) (0.009) dlog(gdpr) t 2 0.021 0.021 0.022 (0.029) (0.028) (0.040) dlog(tech) t 3 0.009 (0.007) dlog(gdpr) t 3 0.065*** (0.024) dlog(es-tech) t 0.079*** (0.009) dlog(es-tech) t 1 0.010 (0.010) dlog(es-tech) t 2-0.012 (0.011) Constant -0.001*** -0.001*** -0.001*** -0.002*** -0.002*** 0.001 (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) Observations 207 207 206 205 101 206 R 2 0.83 0.83 0.84 0.85 0.89 0.79 Akaike IC -1918.33-1915.53-1918.936-1916.402-1001.88-1863.05 DW-stat (p-value) 0.3061 0.5349 0.7093 0.4348 0.5107 0.5840 Robust standard errors in parentheses. * Significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%. 1 Sample from 1986Q1 to 2011Q1. GDPr does not includes the TECH component. 24

Table 6: Dependent Variable: dlog(tech) t (1) (2) (3) (4) dlog(tech) t 1 0.271*** 0.412*** 0.396*** 0.397*** (0.080) (0.107) (0.112) (0.109) log(ceo) t 0.021-0.001 (0.019) (0.029) log(ceo) t 1 0.034 0.034* (0.027) (0.018) Constant 0.017*** 0.009*** 0.009*** 0.009*** (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) Observations 207 93 92 92 R 2 0.07 0.17 0.18 0.19 Akaike IC -881.03-438.62-434.47-436.47 DW-stat (p-value) 0.0000 0.0301 0.1228 0.1192 Robust standard errors in parentheses. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1% Table 7: Dependent Variable: dlog(orders) t (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) dlog(orders) t 1 0.422* 0.320 0.232 0.275 0.222 (0.243) (0.197) (0.178) (0.183) (0.190) log(ceo) t 0.125*** 0.077 0.082 (0.045) (0.061) (0.062) log(ceo) t 1 0.085* 0.107** 0.135*** (0.045) (0.054) (0.033) log(ceo) t 2-0.048 (0.046) Constant 0.004 0.004 0.005 0.005 0.005 (0.005) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) Observations 74 74 74 74 74 R 2 0.17 0.31 0.34 0.35 0.31 Akaike IC -276.68-289.69-292.16-291.70-289.89 DW-stat (p-value) 0.8561 0.0431 0.7646 0.5506 0.4429 Robust standard errors in parentheses. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1% 25

Table 8: Dependent Variable: dlog(tech) t (1) (2) (3) dlog(tech) t 1 0.295** 0.199 0.241* (0.120) (0.125) (0.133) dlog(orders) t 0.195*** 0.169** 0.173** (0.064) (0.079) (0.078) dlog(orders) t 1 0.156 0.150 (0.109) (0.098) dlog(orders) t 2-0.035 (0.066) Constant 0.009** 0.009** 0.009** (0.003) (0.004) (0.004) Observations 75 74 73 R 2 0.23 0.28 0.27 Akaike IC -348.05-347.81-241.46 DW-stat (p-value) 0.0031 0.9620 0.0496 Robust standard errors in parentheses * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1% Table 9: Dependent Variable: dlog(tech) t (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) 1 (6) 2 dlog(tech) t 1 0.256*** 0.258*** 0.251*** 0.246*** 0.248** (0.083) (0.082) (0.082) (0.081) (0.103) dlog(michigan) t -0.012-0.002-0.002 0.001 0.069 0.095*** (0.028) (0.028) (0.027) (0.026) (0.042) (0.026) dlog(michigan) t 1 0.059** 0.063** 0.060** 0.116*** 0.083*** (0.028) (0.028) (0.027) (0.034) (0.020) dlog(michigan) t 2 0.051 0.060* 0.057 0.076*** (0.033) (0.033) (0.038) (0.027) dlog(michigan) t 3 0.042 0.026 0.063** (0.028) (0.032) (0.029) dlog(es-invest) t 1 0.382*** (0.074) Constant 0.017*** 0.017*** 0.017*** 0.017*** 0.011*** 0.010*** (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.002) Observations 204 203 202 201 101 201 R 2 0.06 0.07 0.08 0.09 0.20 0.31 Akaike IC -871.76-869.78-867.01-865.54-480.17-948.49 DW-stat (p-value) 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0014 0.0137 0.0000 Robust standard errors in parentheses; * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1% 1 Sample from 1986Q1 onwards. 2 Dependent variable is dlog(es-tech) t 26

Table 10: Dependent Variable: dlog(tech) t (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) 1 (6) 2 dlog(tech) t 1 0.345*** 0.298*** 0.232** 0.220** 0.197* (0.087) (0.088) (0.091) (0.097) (0.118) dlog(confidence) t 0.047*** 0.045*** 0.053*** 0.054*** 0.052** 0.099*** (0.015) (0.016) (0.017) (0.018) (0.020) (0.018) dlog(confidence) t 1 0.041** 0.042** 0.040** 0.059*** 0.064*** (0.018) (0.017) (0.018) (0.017) (0.015) dlog(confidence) t 2 0.047*** 0.046*** 0.033* 0.060*** (0.017) (0.017) (0.018) (0.016) dlog(confidence) t 3-0.003-0.007 0.033** (0.017) (0.014) (0.014) dlog(es-invest) t 1 0.185** (0.075) Constant 0.013*** 0.014*** 0.015*** 0.015*** 0.012*** 0.012*** (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.002) Observations 134 133 132 131 101 131 R 2 0.16 0.19 0.21 0.2 0.23 0.5 Akaike IC -612.11-610.50-610.01-607.77-484.23-660.62 DW-stat (p-value) 0.0000 0.0000 0.0032 0.0005 0.1693 0.0035 Robust standard errors in parentheses; * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1% 1 Sample from 1986Q1 onwards. 2 Dependent variable is dlog(es-tech) t 27

Table 11: Dependent Variable: dlog(orders) t (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) dlog(orders) t 1 0.423* 0.380* 0.345 0.370** 0.228 0.149 (0.230) (0.209) (0.241) (0.145) (0.138) (0.168) dlog(michigan) t 0.118 0.123 0.121 (0.090) (0.092) (0.088) dlog(michigan) t 1 0.179** 0.187** (0.087) (0.074) dlog(michigan) t 2 0.078 (0.139) dlog(confidence) t 0.142*** 0.140*** 0.143*** (0.047) (0.050) (0.051) dlog(confidence) t 1 0.108*** 0.120*** (0.028) (0.026) dlog(confidence) t 2 0.054 (0.049) Constant 0.004 0.005 0.005 0.004 0.005 0.005 (0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) Observations 74 74 74 74 74 74 R 2 0.18 0.24 0.24 0.32 0.39 0.41 Akaike IC -277.35-281.67-280.92-291.16-298.39-299.05 DW-stat (p-value) 0.0679 0.1808 0.1060 0.0001 0.0328 0.0222 Robust standard errors in parentheses * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1% 28