Are innovation systems complex systems?

Similar documents
Entrepreneurial Structural Dynamics in Dedicated Biotechnology Alliance and Institutional System Evolution

Upper Rhine & creativity : management and policy issues

Why It All Matters. Emergence Economics, Adaptive Policymaking, and the Virtues of Tinkering Without Tampering. Richard S. Whitt Google Inc.

preparing for the future the role of creative cities

Executive Summary Industry s Responsibility in Promoting Responsible Development and Use:

THE IMPLICATIONS OF THE KNOWLEDGE-BASED ECONOMY FOR FUTURE SCIENCE AND TECHNOLOGY POLICIES

Expert Group Meeting on

A Roadmap to Neo-Schumpeterian Economics. by Horst Hanusch and Andreas Pyka University of Augsburg. July 2005

Measuring and benchmarking innovation performance

What is an innovation system? innovation systems and policies? Emmanuel Muller (2009)

Colombia s Social Innovation Policy 1 July 15 th -2014

Innovation system research and policy: Where it came from and Where it might go

KNOWLEDGE MANAGEMENT, ORGANIZATIONAL INTELLIGENCE AND LEARNING, AND COMPLEXITY - Vol. II Complexity and Technology - Loet A.

Canada s Intellectual Property (IP) Strategy submission from Polytechnics Canada

Keywords: DSM, Social Network Analysis, Product Architecture, Organizational Design.

Argumentative Interactions in Online Asynchronous Communication

Information Sociology

What is Digital Literacy and Why is it Important?

A SYSTEMIC APPROACH TO KNOWLEDGE SOCIETY FORESIGHT. THE ROMANIAN CASE

SID AND OUR UNDERSTANDING OF THE EVOLUTION OF INDUSTRIES. Franco Malerba

Ways and means of cooperation along evolutionary economics in the Upper Rhine: the BETA-ISI link

Seoul Initiative on the 4 th Industrial Revolution

Creativity, knowledge and innovation

REPORT D Proposal for a cluster governance model in the Adriatic Ionian macroregion. (Activity 3.4)

Design Constructs for Integration of Collaborative ICT Applications in Innovation Management

Practice Makes Progress: the multiple logics of continuing innovation

Dynamics of National Systems of Innovation in Developing Countries and Transition Economies. Jean-Luc Bernard UNIDO Representative in Iran

Furnari, S. (2016). The Oxford Handbook of Creative Industries. Administrative Science Quarterly, 61(3), NP29-NP32. doi: /

Interrelations between institutions and technology

Some Reflections on Digital Literacy

CHAPTER 1 PURPOSES OF POST-SECONDARY EDUCATION

Creativity, innovation and cluster policy

Playware Research Methodological Considerations

PROJECT FACT SHEET GREEK-GERMANY CO-FUNDED PROJECT. project proposal to the funding measure

Standardization and Innovation Management

EMERGENCE OF COMMUNICATION IN TEAMS OF EMBODIED AND SITUATED AGENTS

ServDes Service Design Proof of Concept

Creating Scientific Concepts

INNOVATION NETWORKS IN THE GERMAN LASER INDUSTRY

Product architecture and the organisation of industry. The role of firm competitive behaviour

Using Emergence to Take Social Innovations to Scale Margaret Wheatley & Deborah Frieze 2006

Lifecycle of Emergence Using Emergence to Take Social Innovations to Scale

Cover Page. The handle holds various files of this Leiden University dissertation.

Human-computer Interaction Research: Future Directions that Matter

Enhancing industrial processes in the industry sector by the means of service design

Contribution of the support and operation of government agency to the achievement in government-funded strategic research programs

BASED ECONOMIES. Nicholas S. Vonortas

Science and Innovation Policies at the Digital Age. Dominique Guellec Science and Technology Policy OECD

A Science & Innovation Audit for the West Midlands

Responsible AI & National AI Strategies

Technology Roadmaps as a Tool for Energy Planning and Policy Decisions

How Books Travel. Translation Flows and Practices of Dutch Acquiring Editors and New York Literary Scouts, T.P. Franssen

Assessing the socioeconomic. public R&D. A review on the state of the art, and current work at the OECD. Beñat Bilbao-Osorio Paris, 11 June 2008

NETWORKED FORESIGHT IN FORWARD LOOKING COMMUNITIES

Role of Knowledge Economics as a Driving Force in Global World

Higher Education for Science, Technology and Innovation. Accelerating Africa s Aspirations. Communique. Kigali, Rwanda.

OECD Science, Technology and Industry Outlook 2008: Highlights

Presentation on the Panel Public Administration within Complex, Adaptive Governance Systems, ASPA Conference, Baltimore, MD, March 2011

Formation Doctorale Strasbourg, 5/02/2016

Privacy, Due Process and the Computational Turn: The philosophy of law meets the philosophy of technology

Intelligent Systems. Lecture 1 - Introduction

Chapter 4. Research Objectives and Hypothesis Formulation

Introduction to Computer Science - PLTW #9340

Indiana K-12 Computer Science Standards

NEW ZEALAND. Evaluation of the Public Good Science Fund An Overview.

Variations on Mobility GeoHumanities Creative Commissions 2019

Glossary of terms. Short explanation

K.1 Structure and Function: The natural world includes living and non-living things.

An Introduction to Agent-based

OECD WORK ON ARTIFICIAL INTELLIGENCE

Trends in TA: Contested futures and prospective knowledge assessment

Centre for the Study of Human Rights Master programme in Human Rights Practice, 80 credits (120 ECTS) (Erasmus Mundus)

NSW Digital+ Public Consultation

TRACING THE EVOLUTION OF DESIGN

R&D and innovation activities in companies across Global Value Chains

University as a Platform for Social Experimentation towards Sustainability Innovation

Faculty of Humanities and Social Sciences

SMALL BUSINESS IN INNOVATIVE DEVELOPMENT OF RUSSIA

Class I - Innovation. Disruptive Innovation Why Lawyers Matter

The 2020 Triangle: Inequality, Systemic Risk and Climate change - Panel Discussion

Werner Wobbe. Employed at the European Commission, Directorate General Research and Innovation

TECHNOLOGY, INNOVATION, and POLICY 3. Series of the Fraunhofer Institute for Systems and Innovation Research (lsi)

design research as critical practice.

Foreknowledge and the management of megaprojects

A Regional University-Industry Cooperation Research Based on Patent Data Analysis

Micro Dynamics of Knowledge - The role of KIBS in Cumulative and Combinatorial Knowledge Dynamics

Research on Catch-up Oriented Industrial Technological Capabilities Growth in Developing Countries

Innovation Dynamics as Co-evolutionary Processes: A Longitudinal Study of the Computer Services Sector in the Region of Attica, Greece

Joining Forces University of Art and Design Helsinki September 22-24, 2005

Section 1: Internet Governance Principles

Tourism network analysis 1

DEPARTMENT OF COMMUNICATIONS. No April 2013 MINISTER OF COMMUNICATIONS OUTLINE OF THE ICT POLICY REVIEW PROCESS, 2013

The Behavior Evolving Model and Application of Virtual Robots

Understanding groupware dynamics

An exploration of the future Latin America and Caribbean (ALC) and European Union (UE) bi-regional cooperation in science, technology and innovation

Innovative Susceptibility in the Regional Innovation System

Synergetic modelling - application possibilities in engineering design

1 The group, chaired by Walter Deffaa (REGIO), included 11 other Directors General and a Deputy Secretary General: M. 2 Ares(2015)

Written response to the public consultation on the European Commission Green Paper: From

Enabling ICT for. development

Transcription:

Are innovation systems complex systems? Emmanuel Muller 1,2 *,Jean-Alain Héraud 2, Andrea Zenker 1 1: Fraunhofer Institute for Systems and Innovation Research ISI, Karlsruhe (Germany) 2: Bureau d'economie Théorique et Appliquée (BETA), Université de Strasbourg (France) *Corresponding author: emmanuel.muller@isi.fraunhofer.de evoreg Research Note #33

Introduction Basically, complex systems are defined as a large number of autonomous entities in interaction, that create several levels of collective organization leading to emergent (and immergent) behavior. In short, complex systems are characterized by the observation that the whole is more than the sum of the parts (Aristotle). The aim of this paper is to address the issue of innovation systems in order to determine by how much they constitute complex systems. Innovation systems are generally used by economists interested in depicting innovation processes, technological changes as well as the emergence of new fields in terms of knowledge, services or business models as an ensemble of resources committed to interrelated activities. Interestingly, only little importance has been given until now by evolutionary economics to the complex-systemic nature of innovation systems. Too often, such systems are just depicted as networks of actors. So far, the main assumption was that an innovation system (e.g. a country, a region, specific sectors or technologies or a private firm) constitutes taken as a whole more than just the sum of its elements and that some feedback loops may be at stake related to processes and interrelations between actors. It is however important to go further in this analysis in considering the key features of innovation processes and thus identifying the reasons explaining why innovation systems may indeed be complex systems. The coordination between the different types of actors involved in the system as well as the existence of mechanisms ensuring a form of governance are at the core of the issue addressed. More precisely, the paper is an attempt to identify possible/thinkable systemic characteristics and properties. The structure of the paper is the following. The first section deals with the concept of innovation as seen by evolutionary economists. The second and third sections consider different hypotheses in particular related to the issues of behavioral patterns and to nonlinear and non-predictable choices. The fourth section attempts to identify some emerging properties of innovation systems seen as complex systems whereas the fifth proposes some reflections about policy implications. 1 What are innovation systems according to evolutionary economics? The father of the analysis of innovation in economics is without contest Joseph Schumpeter (1883-1950) who put forward the concept of creative destruction. According to Schumpeter (1950) this process rules the historical evolution of capitalism. In 1

this respect, five main types of innovation (Schumpeter 1935) can be distinguished: (i) new consumptions objects; (ii) new production and transport methods; (iii) new markets; (iv) new sources of production materials; and (v) new market positions (e.g. monopolistic situation). Following seminal works by Schumpeter the field of evolutionary economics progressively emerged in the 50s and 60s. As a consequence, the concept of innovation systems was developed by authors such as Freeman (1995), Lundvall (1992), etc. At first this concerned mainly the so-called National Systems of Innovation (NSI). This in turn inspired reflections dealing with the sub-national level, i.e. the Regional Systems of Innovation (RSI). This last concept was made popular by authors such as Cooke (1998). Therefore, an innovation system can be considered as a complex system in the sense that it is composed of many subsystems that are different in nature while strongly articulated. Evolutionary economics consider innovation systems mainly under the aspect of creation/selection mechanisms and not so much in the framework of real systemic approach. The simplifying representation of neoclassical economics the market providing all necessary information is just replaced by another global mechanism, the selection process. All in all, the main features of innovation systems in the field of innovation economics can be summarized as follows: (i) central role of learning; (ii) importance of historical processes; (iii) influence of institutions (public actors, legal framework, norms, etc; (iv) existence of feedback loops between non-fully rational actors; and (v) numerous and diverse interrelations between scientific, technological and organizational innovations. A very interesting outcome is that those concepts have a real impact on the conception and application of public policies, especially in European Countries (at national and regional levels) as well as on the level of the European Commission (this point will be developed more extensively in section V). Nevertheless, and despite the wording usually adopted to name such systems, it clearly appears that the systemic nature of innovation systems is not really explored in the corpus of evolutionary economics. The following three sections will try to tackle this issue in presenting arguments in favor of the idea of innovation systems being complex systems. 2 Innovation systems may be complex systems since they are based on complex behavioral patterns The crucial issue to be addressed is the following. If innovation systems are complex systems, what are the mechanisms that explain the mobilization and alignment of resources in an innovative direction? According to the literature, innovation systems are 2

based on complementary mechanisms. The most important of such mechanisms are: (i) interactions; (ii) trial and error procedures; and (iii) selection. Concerning at first interactions, no firm seems to be able to innovate without interactions with the outside world. The forms and the actors involved in such interactions may be extremely heterogeneous but the existence of autarkic innovations seems to be extremely rare if not impossible. At the same time, an underlying process of trial and error can be found in every innovation story. In other words, a first shot success may constitute a very unlikely exception. Moreover, it is helpful to keep in mind that many innovation projects fail. This leads finally to selection phenomena, which concern ideas, production and delivery processes, technologies, marketing approaches, types of interactions and collaboration and even actors (unsuccessful firms). One should be aware that the average life expectancy of companies is far lower than for instance the average human life expectancy. One may easily recognize the evolutionary character of innovation systems. As a consequence, such systems can be seen as the results of complex behaviors of heterogeneous and numerous actors. Moreover, within such systems, different and variable ensembles of resources are committed to interrelated innovation activities (Stamboulis 2008). In other words, innovation systems may be complex systems since some behavioral mechanisms (and not the market as in the neo-classical economic approach) govern the alignment of resources, activities and efforts in innovative directions. These alignments consist in arrangements between actors and result from their to a certain extent implicit and/or opposite strategic decisions. This may be seen as a process of stretch and leverage taking place within an environment characterized by co-operation, connectivity and selection. 3 Innovation systems may be complex systems since they result from non-linear and non-predictable choices Considering the heterogeneity of actors of any innovation system (e.g. firms, academic institutions, public actors, intermediaries, individuals, etc.), the issue can be addressed of what is behind their behaviors, choices and decisions and if those behaviors can be seen as corresponding to elements of complex systems. At least two aspects play a crucial role in this context: First of all, the underlying assumptions of (neo-)classical economics such as perfect competition, full availability of information, atomistic markets, unbounded rationality, etc. are scrutinized and replaced by characteristics like humans opportunistic behaviors, uncertain context conditions such as complex and unstable production environments, evolving structures, learning 3

processes and so forth (see for instance Simon 1957). Scholars in evolutionary economics assume that complex economic processes characterized by variety, technology development, firm evolution, etc. are embedded in and interrelated with dynamic and uncertain contexts. Both parts in our case innovating actors and their environment are influencing each other: Innovators activities can (at least partly) be considered as response to their environment, but the overall environment is in turn also influenced through the activities of embedded innovation actors. The second aspect to be considered refers to individual (innovation-related) actors and their views of the world. It cannot be assumed that the totality of elements in a system (here: innovation actors) behave in the same way, thus acting as a kind of uniform crowd, but that every individual has rather built up his/her individual model of the surrounding world. In short: human beings perceive the world in a specific way and create individual mental models of their surrounding which, in turn, strongly guide their behavior (e.g. Johnson-Laird 1983). Mental models are constructed on the base of memories, experiences, etc. which help to classify and interpret newly perceived information of the external world. Since context conditions including values, rules and habits are largely homogenous within innovation systems (at least in comparison with other systems), it can be assumed that members of the same system have converging views of the world (again compared with members of other systems, cf. for instance Stamboulis 2008). 4 If innovation systems are complex systems what can be deduced from that? Summarizing the three previous sections, it can be stated that the complexity of innovation systems arises from interaction between actors, existence of feed-back loops and non-linearity of processes. Socioeconomic systems like innovation systems are also extremely difficult to describe because individuals have mental representations of the whole system and play strategic roles on the basis of those representations. The strategic orientation of an innovation system results from more than just the sum or the aggregation of individual choices. Game theory applied to economics shows the extreme variety and instability of possible outcomes of strategic models. Nevertheless, even if behaviors cannot be predicted at individual level some patterns may exist and moreover the hypothesis can be formulated that some systemic properties may emerge. This is typically the case in physics, where independent particles in interaction may constitute a fluid, that will implement whorls and eddies under turbulent conditions even though Navier-Stokes equations cannot be found anywhere in the description of the particles. Then, in biology, a number of cells working together will implement an 4

organ with properties going beyond those of each cell (the brains is more than a collection of neurons). Hundreds of ants in interaction will show intelligent behavior (finding the shortest path between their nest and a food source) that is beyond the reach of a single ant. On a higher level, is it possible to make the same observations with social networks (such as the Internet or even the stock exchange market)? Or are they complex systems of another type? Then, observing only a part of a system may not allow drawing conclusions on some other parts. Local robustness is no indication on the robustness of the whole, due to retroactive loops, border effects and reflexive interactions. However, collecting and observing data may allow creating a first model of a complex system that can be refined by subsequent simulations (and comparing the simulations to the observed data). The refined model can then be used to predict what can happen (in probability) in order to prevent catastrophes (in the sense of Thom 1989). Having a complex systems model for innovation systems will allow better understanding and predicting what conditions are needed for innovations to emerge. 5 Implications for policy making Over the last decades, considerable efforts were made by public authorities in order to support economic development at different levels (national, but also regional, European ) with the clear goal of ensuring economic growth as base for employment, income and welfare. Innovation is understood as one means to contribute to economic development and thus wealth creation. On the micro level of business firms, innovation is a means to maintain or broaden market shares and thus to generate benefits. Various policies address economic development, both via influencing the business environment and/or via supporting specific economic actors or actor groups. Fostering innovation follows this logic and often based on the analysis of existing innovation systems introduces interventions in order to create innovation-friendly framework conditions plus promotional measures for (potentially) innovating actors. With the broadening of knowledge and comprehension of innovation processes, policies also broadened and to an increasing extent included additional actors (e.g. from high-tech manufacturing firms to the inclusion of non-tech firms), their interrelations (e.g. collaborative innovation activities) and also switched to integrative policy approaches instead of unconnected approaches of individual policy fields. Equally, learning, exchange and gathering of experience received an increasing role (e.g. demonstrator cases, good examples, etc.). 5

Several evolutionary aspects of innovation systems should be further considered from a perspective of complex systems: the existence of technological trajectories (for instance in the fields of the automotive or aerospace industries); the apparition of hybrid actors and/or mutational effects or even paradigm leaps through the emergence of permissive technologies (such as electricity or ICT); the impacts of learning effects and the resulting acceleration of knowledge flows which may be comparable to a certain extent to forms of swarm intelligence. In consequence, and from a more general point of view, the following assumptions can be formulated in terms of implications for policy making if innovation systems are considered as complex systems. First, innovation-supporting policies should focus on issues related to actors coordination rather than on optimization and efficiency. Second, only holistic innovation policies may be successful in the long-term and policy instruments must aim at providing good contextual conditions, rather than trying to manipulate individual behaviors. Third, and due to the non-linearity of the considered phenomena, if policies lead to mainly unpredictable events, the incentives mobilized by those policies should target marginal systemic effects rather than huge changes. If innovation systems are complex systems, then such approaches may support a reinvention of the role and legitimacy of public interventions dealing with innovation and economic development. Conclusion A better understanding of how far innovation systems can be considered as real complex systems would open new possibilities. In particular, some strong implications for public innovation-led strategies may result from sharper complex dynamics analytical abilities. Nevertheless, the ideas developed in the previous sections are subject to limitations of different nature. First, only a few aspects of the broad spectrum of the concepts developed by academics about innovation systems are taken so far into account. Second, no quantitative data allowing the test of hypothesis are used in this paper. Last but not least, until now no attempt to propose some modeling of innovation systems as complex systems is proposed. Those limitations constitute avenues for future research. 6

References Cooke, P. (1998): Origins of the concept. In: Braczyk, H.-J.; Cooke, P.; Heidenreich, M. (Eds.): Regional Innovation Systems - The Role of Governance in a Globalized World. London: UCL Press, 2-25. Freeman, C. (1995): The 'National System of Innovation' in historical perspective, Cambridge Journal of Economics, 19, 5-24. Johnson-Laird, P.N. (1983): Mental Models. Towards a Cognitive Science of Language, Inference and Consciousness. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Lundvall, B.-Å. (Ed.) (1992): National Systems of Innovation. Towards a Theory of Innovation and Interactive Learning. London: Pinter Publishers. Schumpeter, J.A. (1950): Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. New York: Harper and Brothers. Schumpeter, J.A. (1935): The analysis of economic change, Review of Economic Statistics, 17, 2-10. Simon, H. (1957): Models of Man. New York: Wiley. Stamboulis, Y. (2008): Exploring the System Dynamics of Innovation Systems. Athens, Greece: System Dynamics Society. Online: http://www.systemdynamics.org/conferences/2008/proceed/papers/stamb454. Thom, R. (1989): Structural Stability and Morphogenesis: An Outline of a General Theory of Models. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley. The authors whish to thank Pierre Collet (University of Strasbourg) for his valuable support. 7