April Keywords: Imitation; Innovation; R&D-based growth model JEL classification: O32; O40

Similar documents
I Economic Growth 5. Second Edition. Robert J. Barro Xavier Sala-i-Martin. The MIT Press Cambridge, Massachusetts London, England

R&D Intensity, Technology Transfer and Absorptive Capacity

The Research Agenda: Peter Howitt on Schumpeterian Growth Theory*

Innovation, Diffusion and Trade

Adoption Technology Targets and Knowledge Dynamics: Consequences for Long-Run Prospects

R&D in WorldScan. Paul Veenendaal

Macroeconomics 1 (2015/2016)

INNOVATION AND ECONOMIC GROWTH CASE STUDY CHINA AFTER THE WTO

Understanding R&D Policy: Efficiency or Politics?

202: Dynamic Macroeconomics

Measurement for Generation and Dissemination of Knowledge a case study for India, by Mr. Ashish Kumar, former DG of CSO of Government of India

202: Dynamic Macroeconomics

Kazakhstan Way of Innovation Clusterization K. Mukhtarova Al-Farabi Kazak National University, Almaty, Kazakhstan

The Dynamics of National Innovation Systems: A Panel Cointegration Analysis of the Coevolution between Innovative Capability and Absorptive Capacity

SCIENTIFIC RESEARCH AND INNOVATION - DECISIVE FACTORS OF BUSINESS PERFORMANCE

Measuring productivity and absorptive capacity

Relative Backwardness and Policy Determinants of Technological Catching Up 1

Procedia - Social and Behavioral Sciences 195 ( 2015 ) World Conference on Technology, Innovation and Entrepreneurship

Annex B: R&D, innovation and productivity: the theoretical framework

Convergence Forward and Backward? 1. Quentin Wodon and Shlomo Yitzhaki. World Bank and Hebrew University. March Abstract

How Do Digital Technologies Drive Economic Growth? Research Outline

THE IMPLICATIONS OF THE KNOWLEDGE-BASED ECONOMY FOR FUTURE SCIENCE AND TECHNOLOGY POLICIES

(9,'(1&()520,17(51$7,21$/3$7( L KDHO(3RUWHU 6 RWW6WHUQ :RUNLQJ3DSHU KWWSZZZQEHURUJSDSHUVZ 0DVVD KXVHWWV$YHQXH &DPEULGJH0$ 6HSWHPEHU

Artists, Engineers, and Aspects of Economic Growth in a Creative Region

Internationalisation of STI

Economic growth: technical progress, population dynamics and sustainability

Chapter 2 The Market. The Classical Approach

International Trade and Economic Growth: A Methodology for Estimating Cross-Border R&D Spillovers. Lawrence McNeil* U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis

Technology and Competitiveness in Vietnam

Key Words: direction of technological progress, steady-state, Uzawa s theorem, investment elasticities, factor supply elasticities.

INNOVATION DEVELOPMENT SECTORAL TRAJECTORIES OF THE SOUTH RUSSIAN REGIONS Igor ANTONENKO *

Absorptive capability and economic growth: how do. countries catch-up?

ESSAYS ON TECHNOLOGICAL CHANGE

The Race Between Human and Artificial Intelligence

Research on Catch-up Oriented Industrial Technological Capabilities Growth in Developing Countries

Digital Entrepreneurship barriers and drivers The need for a specific measurement framework

Patent Protection, Innovation Rate and Welfare

Module 5: Conditional convergence and long-run economic growth practice problems. (The attached PDF file has better formatting.)

The Role of the Government in Facilitating TFP Growth. during Japan s Rapid Growth Era

AI and Economic Growth. Philippe Aghion Banque de France 18 June 2018

General aspects of the technological approach to international trade

On the Mechanics of Technical Change: New and Old Ideas in Economic Growth*

BASED ECONOMIES. Nicholas S. Vonortas

INNOVATION VERSUS INCOME CONVERGENCE IN CENTRAL AND EASTERN EUROPE. IS THERE A CORRELATION?*

SMALL BUSINESS IN INNOVATIVE DEVELOPMENT OF RUSSIA

COMPETITIVNESS, INNOVATION AND GROWTH: THE CASE OF MACEDONIA

Research, innovation and economic growth. Technology diffusion

R&D, Implementation and Stagnation: A Schumpeterian Theory of Convergence Clubs

Looking Abroad, but Lagging Behind: How the World Technology Frontier Affects South Africa

Lecture notes 6: The Role of Technology in Growth and Development

THE ROLE OF TECHNOLOGY IN GROWTH

Innovation policies to promote more inclusive growth: comments

The dynamics of technology, growth and trade: A Schumpeterian perspective

The most recent advancement of endogenous growth theory has been the emergence

Technology-gap and cumulative growth: models, results and performances

How can innovation contribute to economic growth?

Public and private R&D Spillovers

Dynamics of National Systems of Innovation in Developing Countries and Transition Economies. Jean-Luc Bernard UNIDO Representative in Iran

THE EVOLUTION OF TECHNOLOGY DIFFUSION AND THE GREAT DIVERGENCE

The drivers of productivity dynamics over the last 15 years 1

Chapter 8. Technology and Growth

Trade, Foreign Direct Investment, and International Technology Transfer: A Survey*

Understanding the Switch from Virtuous to Bad Cycles in the Finance-Growth Relationship

DETERMINANTS OF STATE ECONOMIC GROWTH: COMPLEMENTARY RELATIONSHIPS BETWEEN R&D AND HUMAN CAPITAL

An Empirical Look at Software Patents (Working Paper )

Information Societies: Towards a More Useful Concept

Green policies, clean technology spillovers and growth Antoine Dechezleprêtre London School of Economics

Financial Factors in Business Fluctuations

NEW INDUSTRIAL POLICY

This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Sciences Research Network Electronic Paper Collection:

Why is US Productivity Growth So Slow? Possible Explanations Possible Policy Responses

CHAPTER 1 TOWARD ENDOGENOUS ECONOMIC GROWTH

CEP Discussion Paper No 723 May Basic Research and Sequential Innovation Sharon Belenzon

Finance and Growth: Modern Interpretations of the. Thoughts of Schumpeter

Innovation and Inclusive Growth in Emerging Economies. Poh Kam Wong Professor, NUS Business School Director, NUS Entrepreneurship Centre

Country Innovation Brief: Costa Rica

OECD Innovation Strategy: Key Findings

How Technological Advancement Affects Economic Growth of Emerging Countries

Economic and Social Council

Looking Abroad, But Lagging Behind: How Technology Shocks in the US Affect South Africa

Estimating innovation input output matrix and innovation linkages in the East Asian region and the USA

Transition Dynamics in Vintage Capital Models: Explaining the Postwar Catch-Up of Germany and Japan

Oesterreichische Nationalbank. Eurosystem. Workshops Proceedings of OeNB Workshops. Current Issues of Economic Growth. March 5, No.

Dr Ioannis Bournakis

Why is US Productivity Growth So Slow? Possible Explanations Possible Policy Responses

Unified Growth Theory and Comparative Economic Development. Oded Galor. AEA Continuing Education Program

Why did the Japanese economy stop growing over time? Why did technological progress in Japan decline?

Tailoring deployment policies to support innovation in specific energy technologies

Implications of the New Growth Theory to Agricultural Trade Research and Trade Policy

Multinational enterprises, technology diffusion, and host country productivity growth

EERC Research Competition Spring 2013 DETERMINANTS OF PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES: WHAT REALLY MATTERS?

National Intellectual Property Systems, Innovation and Economic Development Framework for Country Analysis. Dominique Guellec

More of the same or something different? Technological originality and novelty in public procurement-related patents

Service Science: A Key Driver of 21st Century Prosperity

New Paradigm of Korean Economy: To be More Creative and Innovative

China s technology transformation: Diffusion and intensification of R&D effort in China s firms and research institutes

Graduate School of Economics Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo Ph.D. Course Dissertation. November, 1997 SUMMARY

Localized and Biased Technologies: Atkinson and Stiglitz s New View, Induced Innovations, and Directed Technological Change

An analysis of knowledge spillover from information and communication technology in. Australia, Japan, South Korea and Taiwan

Statement by the BIAC Committee on Technology and Industry on THE IMPACT OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY PROTECTION ON INNOVATION AND TECHNOLOGY DEVELOPMENT

Transcription:

Imitation in a non-scale R&D growth model Chris Papageorgiou Department of Economics Louisiana State University email: cpapa@lsu.edu tel: (225) 578-3790 fax: (225) 578-3807 April 2002 Abstract. Motivated by recent empirical evidence this paper extends a nonscale R&D growth model to allow for technological imitation in addition to innovation. It is shown that a simple modification of the standard R&D equation results in a more general model that can explain not only the growth process of developed countries that mostly innovate, but also the growth process of developing countries that mostly imitate. Keywords: Imitation; Innovation; R&D-based growth model JEL classification: O32; O40 I am thank Craig Burnside, David Dejong, John Duffy, Chad Jones, Jack Ochs, Fidel Perez-Sebastian and Robert Solow for their comments and suggestions. All remaining errors are my own.

Imitation in a non-scale R&D growth model 2 1. Introduction Recent work by Helpman and Hoffmaister (1997) reveals that even though technological innovation is crucial to economic growth, only a small group of industrial countries account for most of the world s innovation. Helpman and Hoffmaister find that, within the OECD, the seven largest economies accounted for over 90% of R&D in 1991. They also report that in 1990, industrial countries accounted for 96% of the world s R&D expenditure. This evidence suggests that the pioneer R&D growth models (i.e. Romer (1990), Grossman and Helpman (1991), Aghion and Howitt (1992), and Jones (1995a) (R-GH-AH-J)) are applicable only to the developed countries that innovate. This paper extends a non-scale R&D growth model to make it applicable not only to the few countries that innovate but also to most countries that imitate. The three main features of the model presented here are the following: First, it preserves the appealing monopolistically competitive structure of the R&D growth models. Second, it is consistent with the Jones (1995a, 1995b) prediction that in the long-run there are no scale effects. Third, it allows for technological imitation thus becoming applicable to most countries that grow mainly through adoption of existing technologies. Even though the paper is similar in structure to R-GH-AH-J, it is closer in spirit to Nelson and Phelps (1966), Benhabib and Spiegel (1994, 2000, 2002), Parente and Prescott (1994), Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1997), and Perez-Sebastian (2000). 1 2. The Model The leader-follower model presented below is a variant of the Jones (1995a) non-scale R&D growth model where technical progress and long-run growth is the outcome of expansion of the set of intermediate goods. The only difference between the leader and the follower country is that the leader only innovates where the follower re-invents as well as imitates existing technology. 2 The model economy consists of three sectors: The final-good sector which is perfectly competitive and produces a single homogenous consumption good. The monopolistically competitive intermediate-goods sector that supplies a variety of inputs to the final-good s producers. Finally, the R&D sector that supplies the intermediate-goods producer with different designs/blueprints. 1 For a list of other papers on technological imitation and growth see Benhabib and Spiegel (2002). 2 Re-invention is the process of building one s own version of existing technology without adopting it from abroad.

Imitation in a non-scale R&D growth model 3 Since our model follows closely the basic structure of the standard R&D growth model, detailed presentation of the decentralized problem is omitted. 3 Instead, we present the equations that characterize our model with primary attention to the modified R&D equation which is the primary innovation of the paper. The follower and the leader countries are structurally the same and are characterized by two equations. First, the production function of final and intermediate goods is given by Z A Y =(L Y ) 1 α (X i ) α di, (1) where Y is output, L Y is the portion of labor employed in the output sector, X i is the amount of intermediate good i, A is a domestic technology index denoting the number of intermediate goods used in output production, and α (0, 1) is the share of intermediate good X i in output. Second, the law of motion of technology is given by 4 Ȧ =[δl λ A A]γ [µl λ A (A A )]1 γ, (2) where L A is the portion of labor employed in the R&D sector, A is the stock of foreign technology (leader s technology), δ, µ (0, 1) are innovation and imitation parameters respectively, λ (0, 1) is a parameter that allows for the possibility of duplication, and γ (0, 1) is the technology share. There are a number of points worth making here. First, notice equation (2) is an extended version of the Jones (1995a) R&D equation that includes an imitation term. 5 The extended R&D equation can best be described by referring to the two RHS terms of equation (2), [δl λ AA] γ and [µl λ A( A A )]1 γ. The former term, [δl λ AA] γ, represents the ability of a country to grow by innovating (or re-inventing) new (existing) varieties of intermediate goods. The second term, [µl λ A( A A )]1 γ, is the main contribution of this model and captures the potential for a follower country to imitate. It states that imitation is a function of labor employed A in the business of adopting existing technology, L A, and a catching-up term,. The A 3 The decentralized problem is presented in the working paper version and is available by the author upon request. 4 Nelson and Phelps (1966) were the first to formally incorporate the notion of technological adoption into a model. More recently, Benhabib and Spiegel (1994, 2000, 2002) have provided empirical evidence supporting technological adoption as a primary engine of growth in developing countries. 5 It is not necessary that the innovation and imitation processes be characterized by the same specification. Nevertheless, it is reasonable to assume that the two processes are similar and that can conveniently be incorporated into a single specification. 0

Imitation in a non-scale R&D growth model 4 catch-up term captures the idea that the greater the technology gap between a leader and a follower, the higher the potential of the follower to catch up through imitation. The catchingup term is also consistent with the relative backwardness hypothesis of Findlay (1978) that the rate of technological progress in a relatively backward country is an increasing function of the gap between its own level of technology and that of the advanced country. Notice however that in our formulation relative backwardness is one of two ingredients necessary for imitation. The other necessary ingredient that enhances the catch-up term is labor in R&D. A novel property of the modified R&D equation is that it encompasses technical progress in countries that lie on the frontier and thus only innovate. Since imitation is not possible in these countries, their R&D equation is reduced to A = δl λ A(A ) γ that is very similar to that of Jones (1995a). 6 Finally, notice that regarding the follower countries, equation (2) implies that scientist and engineers foster both re-invention as well as adoption of new technologies. Notice that latecomers with low A and high L A have the potential to grow much faster than the leader because of the catching-up effect. Steady-state growth As mentioned previously, an important property of the modified R&D equation proposed above is that for the leading country for which technology level is A, equation (2) is reduced to a version of Jones (1995a) specification as follows: A = δl λ A (A ) γ. (3) Therefore the steady-state growth of the leader is virtually identical to that of Jones (1995a) ga ss = λn 1 γ, (4) where n is the exogenous growth rate of labor in the leader country. The steady state growth of the follower country is easily determined by totally differentiating equation (2) around its steady state as g ss A = λn 1 γ + gss A 2 λ (n + n ) 2(1 γ) (5) 6 This follows directly by replacing A with A in equation (2) and assuming that δ = µ inthecaseof the leader country. A minor difference between this specification and that of Jones, is that now γ denotes a technological externality as well as a technological share.

Imitation in a non-scale R&D growth model 5 where n is the exogenous growth rate of labor in the follower country (to avoid leapfrogging we assume that n n ), and g A is the balanced growth rate of the leader economy. Equation (5) states that the balanced growth path of the follower is the arithmetic mean of its own growth and the growth of the leader. The steady-state comparative statics associated with long-run growth are gss A, gss n A, gss A, gss A > 0. n λ γ If we assume that technology share, γ, and duplication parameter, λ, are identical in all countries, then at steady state the follower country may enjoy at most the same growth rate as that of the leader depending on n. In the special case where the exogenous growth rate of labor is the same in the leader and the follower countries (i.e. n = n )theng A = g A. Transitional growth The transitional dynamics of the modified R&D equation (2) are investigated by running simulation exercises. Off-steady-state analysis is important in this model because it shows how a follower country s technology converges towards its steady state. Parameters used in our baseline simulation are presented in table 1. In running this simulation, we assume that Table 1: Parameter values for the baseline simulation n 0.01 δ 0.1 L 0 1 γ 0.5 µ 0.01 A 0 10 λ 0.5 g ss A 0.5 A 0 1 technology growth of the leader country is given exogenously to the follower countries, and it is set to obtain a steady-state value of g A =0.02, to approximately match the average percapitagrowthrateoftheu.s.overthepostwarperiod. Wealsoassumeapermanent one percent increase in the level of labor (n = 0.01) and initial levels of labor and technology to be L 0 = 1, A 0 = 10, and A 0 = 1. The rest of the parameters δ,µ,γ, and λ, are chosen to match commonly found values in the empirical literature and to impose the simplifying assumption that ga ss = g A =0.02. 7 Figure 1 illustrates the transitional path of the modified R&D equation resulting from 7 Estimates of λ found in the literature vary from 0.2(Kortum(1993)) to 0.75 (Jones and Williams (2000)). Even though there are no empirical estimates for γ most theoretical models assume γ 1/2 which implies nonnegative externalities of domestic technology.

Imitation in a non-scale R&D growth model 6 Figure 1: Transitional growth path: Jones vs modified R&D equation the simulation exercise. A noticeable feature of figure 1 is that the transitional growth of the follower is much faster than that predicted by Jones (1995a) model. This is expected since the follower s technological accumulation is now subject to two external effects (rather than one in Jones): the first is due to the existing domestic technology and the second is due to existing foreign technology. To better understand the properties of the modified R&D equation, we examine how changes in relevant parameters affect the transitional growth path. Sensitivity analyses, on the parameters δ (or µ), γ, λ, the initial technology gap A 0/A 0, the initial level of labor L 0, and the leader s steady state growth g A, reveal some interesting insights. Figure 2A illustrates that a uniform increase in the domestic innovation parameter δ (or a proportional increase in the foreign adoption parameter µ),wouldresultinmuchhigher transitional growth path. Figure 2B reveals the importance of technological gap in this model. It shows that, everything else being equal, the wider the technology gap between the follower and the leader, the higher the transitional growth. This suggests that the further away the follower is from the technological frontier (i.e. the larger the ratio A )thegreater A its potential to grow rapidly by taking advantage of existing foreign technologies. Figure 2C shows that the initial level of labor is crucial in determining the ability of a country to adopt existing technology. The role of labor in this model is more important than that in Jones

Imitation in a non-scale R&D growth model 7 Figure 2: Sensitivity analysis of baseline simulation

Imitation in a non-scale R&D growth model 8 (1995a) in the sense that it enhances both innovation and imitation. Notice that changes in δ, µ, A 0/A 0, and L 0 can affect only the transitional growth and not the long-run growth rate. Figures 2D, 2E, and 2F show how changes in γ, λ, and ga influence transitional growth. Figure 2D reveals that a positive deviation from the baseline technological share parameter γ results in higher transitional and steady state growth. Figure 2E shows that the same is true when the duplication parameter λ increases. Finally, figure 2F illustrates how an increase in the steady-state growth of the leader results in higher transitional and steady-state growth for the follower. 8 3. Conclusion The most important feature of the modified R&D-based model examined above is its emphasis on technological transfers as a major determinant of growth in developing countries. The model predicts that developing economies possessing sufficiently high levels of labor can take advantage of existing technologies through the process of technological adoption and grow rapidly for a long time. However, as they continue to exploit the growth potential from technological transfers, at the same time they narrow down their technological gap with the leader which makes adoption less feasible. Another favorable features of the model is its simplicity. A single law of motion of technical change incorporates both the processes of innovation\re-invention and imitation. The models steady-state predictions retain the favorable property of the non-scale effects while its transitional dynamics account for faster convergence to the steady state due to the imitation technology. 8 Experiments with a large number of alternative sets of parameters do not change the results qualitatively.

References Imitation in a non-scale R&D growth model 9 Aghion, P. and Howitt, P., A Model of Growth Through Creative Destruction, Econometrica, 60:323 51, 1992. Barro, R. and Sala i Martin X., Technological Diffusion, Convergence, and Growth, Journal of Economic Growth, 2:1 26, 1997. Benhabib, J. and Spiegel, M., The Role of labor in Economic Development: Evidence from Cross Country Data, Journal of Monetary Economics, 34:143 173, 1994. Benhabib, J. and Spiegel, M., The Role of Financial Development in Growth and Investment, Journal of Economic Growth, 5:341 360, 2000. Benhabib, J. and Spiegel, M., Human Capital as a Facilitator of Technological Progress: Theory and Evidence, working paper, Federal Reserve of San Francisco, 2002. Findlay, R., Relative Backwardness, Direct Foreign Investment and the Transfer of Technology: A Simple Dynamic Model, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 92:1 16, 1978. Grossman, M. and Helpman, E., Quality Ladders in the Theory of Growth, Review of Economic Studies, 58:43 61, 1991. Helpman, E. and Hoffmaister, A., North-South R&D Spillovers, TheEconomicJournal, 107:134 149, 1997. Jones, C.I, R&D-Based Models of Economic Growth, Journal of Political Economy, 103:759 784, 1995a. Jones, C.I, Time Series Tests of Endogenous Growth Models, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110:495 525, 1995b. Jones, C.I, and Williams, J., Too Much of a Good Thing: The Economics of Investment in R&D, Journal of Economic Growth, 5:65 85, 2000. Kortum, S., Equilibrium R&D and the Decline in the Patent-R&D Ratio; U.S. Evidence, American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings, 83:450 457, 1993. Nelson, R. and Phelps, E., Investment in Humans, Technological Diffusion, and Economic Growth, American Economic Review, 69 83, 1966. Parente, S. and Prescott, E., Barriers to Technology Adoption and Development, Journal of Political Economy, 102:298 321, 1994. Perez-Sebastian, F., Transitional Dynamics in an R&D-Based Growth Model with Imitation: Comparing its Predictions to the Data, Journal of Monetary Economics, 45:437 461, 2000. Romer, P., Endogenous Technological Change, Journal of Political Economy, 98: S71 S96, 1990.