Charles River Associates Annual Conference 8 December 2010, Brussels Opening address: The interplay between law and economics

Similar documents
The Role of the Intellectual Property Office

DERIVATIVES UNDER THE EU ABS REGULATION: THE CONTINUITY CONCEPT

Intellectual property and competition policy

Submission to the Productivity Commission inquiry into Intellectual Property Arrangements

Lexis PSL Competition Practice Note

IS STANDARDIZATION FOR AUTONOMOUS CARS AROUND THE CORNER? By Shervin Pishevar

TechAmerica Europe comments for DAPIX on Pseudonymous Data and Profiling as per 19/12/2013 paper on Specific Issues of Chapters I-IV

10246/10 EV/ek 1 DG C II

IAASB Main Agenda (March, 2015) Auditing Disclosures Issues and Task Force Recommendations

Organisation de Coopération et de Développement Économiques Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development

"Competition Policy and Intellectual Property Rights in the Republic of Latvia since 1991" (the working title)

Strategic Patenting and Registration of Healthcare Products

Conclusions concerning various issues related to the development of the European Research Area

Building Collaborative Networks for Innovation

THE LABORATORY ANIMAL BREEDERS ASSOCIATION OF GREAT BRITAIN

Committee on Development and Intellectual Property (CDIP)

Settlement of Pharma Disputes and Competition Law in Korea

Globalisation increasingly affects how companies in OECD countries

Counterfeit, Falsified and Substandard Medicines

Competition Policy and Sector-Specific Regulation for Network Industries. November 2004

I hope you will find these comments constructive and helpful.

OECD Innovation Strategy: Key Findings

Fact Sheet IP specificities in research for the benefit of SMEs

16502/14 GT/nj 1 DG G 3 C

An Essential Health and Biomedical R&D Treaty

Our position. ICDPPC declaration on ethics and data protection in artificial intelligence

GCR THE HANDBOOK OF COMPETITION ECONOMICS. A Global Competition Review special report published in association with: Copenhagen Economics

SAUDI ARABIAN STANDARDS ORGANIZATION (SASO) TECHNICAL DIRECTIVE PART ONE: STANDARDIZATION AND RELATED ACTIVITIES GENERAL VOCABULARY

TRAINING SEMINAR PHARMACEUTICALS AND INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY ACCESS TO MEDICINE: Exploitation of pharmaceutical patents: compulsory licences SESSION 4

ESA. European Seed Association. Community Plant Variety Rights System views of the European seed industry

COMMISSION STAFF WORKING PAPER EXECUTIVE SUMMARY OF THE IMPACT ASSESSMENT. Accompanying the

Guidelines on Standardization and Patent Pool Arrangements

NZFSA Policy on Food Safety Equivalence:

DRAFT AGENDA. OECD/Korean Policy Centre. Workshop on Merger Review Procedures and Joint Ventures. MOFCOM - Beijing, 25 June 2014

Cover Page. The handle holds various files of this Leiden University dissertation.

SATELLITE NETWORK NOTIFICATION AND COORDINATION REGULATIONS 2007 BR 94/2007

MEASURES TO SUPPORT SMEs IN THE EUROPEAN UNION

Progress in FDA s Drug Product Quality Initiative. Janet Woodcock, M.D. November 13, 2003

TOOL #21. RESEARCH & INNOVATION

Mr Hans Hoogervorst Chairman International Accounting Standards Board 30 Cannon Street London EC4M 6XH United Kingdom

Guidelines for the Professional Evaluation of Digital Scholarship by Historians

Pan-Canadian Trust Framework Overview

Keynote Speech. at the. Trilateral User Conference "CHALLENGES FACING THE GLOBAL PATENT SYSTEM"

The Information Commissioner s response to the Draft AI Ethics Guidelines of the High-Level Expert Group on Artificial Intelligence

E5 Implementation Working Group Questions & Answers (R1) Current version dated June 2, 2006

Technology Platforms: champions to leverage knowledge for growth

Written response to the public consultation on the European Commission Green Paper: From

Working together to deliver on Europe 2020

"Workshops on key economic issues regarding the. enforcement of IPR in the European Union"

European Commission. 6 th Framework Programme Anticipating scientific and technological needs NEST. New and Emerging Science and Technology

BUREAU OF LAND MANAGEMENT INFORMATION QUALITY GUIDELINES

RESOLUTION MEPC.290(71) (adopted on 7 July 2017) THE EXPERIENCE-BUILDING PHASE ASSOCIATED WITH THE BWM CONVENTION

Patenting Strategies. The First Steps. Patenting Strategies / Bernhard Nussbaumer, 12/17/2009 1

Impact and Innovation in H2020 Proposals and projects

U.S. Patent-Antitrust Interface. Alden F. Abbott, Heritage Foundation Oxford Competition Law Centre June 28, 2014

CBD Request to WIPO on the Interrelation of Access to Genetic Resources and Disclosure Requirements

Proposed International Standard on Auditing 315 (Revised) Identifying and Assessing the Risks of Material Misstatement

Directions in Auditing & Assurance: Challenges and Opportunities Clarified ISAs

DIGITAL TRANSFORMATION LESSONS LEARNED FROM EARLY INITIATIVES

China: Managing the IP Lifecycle 2018/2019

By RE: June 2015 Exposure Draft, Nordic Federation Standard for Audits of Small Entities (SASE)

Definitions proposals for draft Framework for state aid for research and development and innovation Document Original text Proposal Notes

The Interdisciplinary Centre for Competition Law and Policy (ICC) and Crowell & Moring LLP Annual Conference 2014

Justice Select Committee: Inquiry on EU Data Protection Framework Proposals

The Ubiquity and Limits of Competition Policy in a World of Flux

Impact on audit quality. 1 November 2018

LAW ON TECHNOLOGY TRANSFER 1998

Copernicus Evolution: Fostering Growth in the EO Downstream Services Sector

Report OIE Animal Welfare Global Forum Supporting implementation of OIE Standards Paris, France, March 2018

What does the revision of the OECD Privacy Guidelines mean for businesses?

COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT. pursuant to Article 294(6) of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union

CERN-PH-ADO-MN For Internal Discussion. ATTRACT Initiative. Markus Nordberg Marzio Nessi

Freedom of Information Act 2000 (FOIA) Decision notice

MINISTRY OF HEALTH STAGE PROBITY REPORT. 26 July 2016

PRIMATECH WHITE PAPER COMPARISON OF FIRST AND SECOND EDITIONS OF HAZOP APPLICATION GUIDE, IEC 61882: A PROCESS SAFETY PERSPECTIVE

Response to. Second Consultation on Possible National Rollout Scenarios for the Smart Metering Cost Benefit Analysis (CER/10/197)

Globalizing IPR Protection: How Important Might RTAs Be?

GLOBAL RISK AND INVESTIGATIONS JAPAN CAPABILITY STATEMENT

EFRAG s Draft letter to the European Commission regarding endorsement of Definition of Material (Amendments to IAS 1 and IAS 8)

HORIZON2020 and State Aid Rules Maria da Graça Carvalho

The ICT industry as driver for competition, investment, growth and jobs if we make the right choices

18 The Impact of Revisions of the Patent System on Innovation in the Pharmaceutical Industry (*)

Establishing a Development Agenda for the World Intellectual Property Organization

Draft executive summaries to target groups on industrial energy efficiency and material substitution in carbonintensive

strong patents, weak patents and evergreening: should patents for drugs be challenged more often? Giancarlo Del Corno Studio Legale Sena e Tarchini

Final results of the Commission pharmaceutical sector inquiry: competition and regulatory concerns to address

March 27, The Information Technology Industry Council (ITI) appreciates this opportunity

Identifying and Managing Joint Inventions

NEW 2LDS ADVISORY PANEL. RECOMMENDATIONS TO THE auda BOARD, AUGUST In December 2009 the auda board established the New 2LDs Advisory Panel to:

South West Public Engagement Protocol for Wind Energy

Mde Françoise Flores, Chair EFRAG 35 Square de Meeûs B-1000 Brussels Belgium January Dear Mde.

White paper The Quality of Design Documents in Denmark

The creation of the Emergency Preparedness and Response Expert Group (EPREG) which held its second meeting last month.

Details of the Proposal

COMMERCIAL INDUSTRY RESEARCH AND DEVELOPMENT BEST PRACTICES Richard Van Atta

Question Q 159. The need and possible means of implementing the Convention on Biodiversity into Patent Laws

15890/14 MVG/cb 1 DG G 3 C

The Interdisciplinary Centre for Competition Law and Policy (ICC) and Crowell & Moring LLP Annual Conference 2009

Extract of Advance copy of the Report of the International Conference on Chemicals Management on the work of its second session

EVCA Strategic Priorities

Transcription:

Charles River Associates Annual Conference 8 December 2010, Brussels Opening address: The interplay between law and economics Alexander ITALIANER Director General Directorate General for Competition European Commission 1

Introduction Ladies and Gentlemen, I am delighted to be here today and to share my views with you on the relationship between law and economics in the application of our competition rules. This year, the European Courts have ruled on a number of competition law cases where economic analysis has played a key role. In particular, the Courts have strongly validated the Commission's increased focus on economic analysis in both mergers and unilateral conduct cases. I will refer to these cases throughout my address of today. I will start by highlighting the increased importance that economics has come to play in constructing our competition cases. I will refer then to the current interplay between law and economics against the background of the standards of proof that the European Courts require. 1. Development of the use of economics in competition law enforcement 1.1 Increased economic analysis across instruments and sectors Let me start with a few remarks on how economics became integrated into competition law enforcement over the last two decades. It is widely known that the role of economics has grown significantly over this period. I will briefly mention a few highlights of this historical development that started in the merger field, and then spread to other instruments. The introduction of the Merger Regulation in 1989 marked an increased use of economic analysis, and economics influenced the evolution of our substantive merger test in 2004. After a few years, we understood largely as a result of economic analysis that it was better to clarify the then prevailing test on 2

dominance in order to ensure that all potentially harmful mergers could be caught by the Merger Regulation. This is why we moved to the "significant impediment to effective competition" test the so-called SIEC test in the 2004 Regulation. By the time of these 2004 revisions, this more effects-based approach had already spread from mergers through to antitrust, with the revision of the horizontal and vertical guidelines in the late 1990s. State aid followed shortly after, with the Action Plan of 2005. We have made substantial progress on the overall framework for a more economic approach to State aid, and on how to analyse certain areas such as R&D and environmental aid, but we still need to gather experience in other sectors. In some policy areas this increased focus on economic effects was first driven by the Commission notably on mergers. In other areas such as Article 101 we were first led by the Court. In both cases, the development of the law over time was based on the work of both institutions. I will give you detailed examples later on. These developments in policy went side by side with changes to how DG Competition deals with economics on a day to day basis. The role of economics was boosted with the nomination of a chief Competition Economist and the creation of the Chief Economist Team in 2003. Damien Neven will also address you today. The Team which he has successfully led for four years has marked a "step-change" in the integration of economic thinking into our enforcement work, and Damien deserves all the credit for this. The contribution of our in-house economists is not limited to quantitative econometric work. Our economists are now fully involved in the development of conceptual frameworks for our cases and our overall policy-making. Recent examples include guidance on non-horizontal mergers, Article 102 Enforcement Priorities or horizontal agreements in antitrust, and state aid policy. Our economic work is also integrated into the overall sectoral approach on which the Commission focuses. In this respect, the work we are carrying-out to understand market dynamics and to remedy sectoral market malfunctions is very relevant. 3

I will mention only one example the pharmaceutical sector inquiry completed last year. We conducted an extensive empirical study to assess the extent and timing of market entry of generic medicines and the effect of such penetration on average drug prices in European markets. This contributed to an informed understanding of potential competition problems within the pharmaceutical sector. Because economics had become so embedded in competition policy, it was time for the Commission to explain how we dealt with economic evidence. This is why we drafted the Best Practices on the submission of economic evidence in early 2010. 1.2 The Best Practices on the submission of economic evidence These Best Practices were provisionally adopted and implemented for both antitrust and merger proceedings. The Best Practices crystallise the experience we have accumulated over the last years on receiving and processing economic evidence. Their aim is to explain how we deal with economic evidence and to set clear standards for its submission by parties and third parties. The Best Practices aim to facilitate the assessment of the evidence and the replication of any empirical results by our teams or other parties. We also provide guidance on how to respond to our requests for quantitative data so as to ensure timely and relevant input for the investigation. We have received a very positive response to this initiative. I can tell you today that the Best Practices have already helped in a large number of cases to gather quantitative data and to limit the scope of data requests. As a consequence, we have received improved submissions over the last months in both merger and antitrust cases. As I mentioned, the Best Practices were largely a codification of existing practice, perhaps best exemplified by the Commission's analysis in the Ryanair case, where we put forward extensive qualitative and quantitative evidence. I want now to say a few words about that case, and in particular the Court judgment. 4

1.3. Ryanair In its judgment of July this year, the General Court upheld the Commission s decision to prohibit Ryanair's proposed acquisition of AerLingus. In doing so, the Court did not shy away from a detailed review of the economic evidence put before it. It engaged in a detailed discussion of the extensive econometric evidence put forward by the Commission and by the parties in order to assess the impact of the transaction. To take just a few textual examples, the judgement refers to "panel and crosssection regressions", "fixed effects" and "two-stage regressions". The importance of the Ryanair judgement is far-reaching. In addition to confirming that the Commission had been right on the substance, the Ryanair ruling also validated the process we had followed in terms of interacting with the parties to confront the econometric evidence. And this is important feedback for us since it echoes the same approach taken in our Best Practices. There are already beneficial effects deriving from these Best Practices. Most recently, the Unilever / Sara Lee merger was perhaps another good example. We had numerous interactions with the consultants to the parties at various stages of the data gathering, the development of the evidence and the cross examination of our (and their) evidence. 2. The interplay put to the test I have given you examples that highlight where we have come to in terms of building economic analysis into our case practice. However we must all bear in mind that we ultimately have to prove our cases before a court. And when we prove our cases we do not do it to an economic standard, but to a legal one. The key point here is that we are in fact using economic analysis to support the construction of legally robust cases. 5

2.1 Merger cases The feedback we receive from the Courts through the case law is that they are ready and able to conduct an effective review. We take that feedback and integrate it into our practice. Let me take a few merger-related examples to illustrate this point. - In the Impala judgment of 2008 overturning the CFI decision on the Sony/BMG merger, the ECJ fully endorsed the economic model of tacit coordination between parties. The Court used this occasion to invite the Commission to go beyond a "checklist approach" in its cases and to develop a coherent narrative on how such coordination would operate. - The Commission s ABF/GBI decision adopted shortly after is fully in line with the standard established by the Court in this respect. In ABF/GBI we assessed whether the transaction would likely lead to coordinated effects by making tacit or explicit collusion more likely, stable or effective. We went beyond a simple checklist approach and tried to understand how coordination would actually work in practice. - This approach implied an in-depth understanding of the likely collusive mechanism. We had to understand what variables the colluding partners would agree upon and what mechanism they would use to retaliate against deviations from the collusive agreement. An analysis of the upstream and downstream dynamics of the industry was crucial to solving this case. As well as showing the interplay between the Court and the Commission, these examples also confirm the intricate relationship between law and economics in putting together a case. They show that economics can help us to identify the parameters of a case - the factors relevant to showing harm. Both quantitative and qualitative analysis can then contribute to assessing whether those factors are present in a particular case. Assessment of evidence requires both legal and economic input. The two are inseparable. Ultimately, however, this is a question of being able to present a coherent story, a narrative of the operation of the market that fulfils the legal standard of proof. 6

And this is where we have come to today. It is the interplay of law and economics that allows us to put forward legally robust cases that can successfully go through the scrutiny of the European Courts. I will turn now to what some see as a more difficult area Article 102. 2. 2. Effects-based approach in abuse of dominance cases There is relatively little debate about the use of economics in mergers and about the role of the Court in such cases. But this is perceived as a more delicate topic in cases involving Article 102. In such cases, some portray the Commission as pushing for a more economic approach and argue that the Courts act as more of a barrier. I think this is a somewhat misguided perception. It shows a certain lack of understanding of how law and economics inter-relate and of how jurisprudence develops: - First, it may be economically appropriate to have clear-cut rules, even if that doesn't always lead to the perfect result in a particular case. There is an economic benefit to legal certainty, and to reducing compliance costs, which may outweigh the costs of false positives and false negatives. - Second, a Court deciding on the interpretation of a legal rule is largely constrained by the arguments of the parties before it, and by the general knowledge existing at that point in time. Assessment of these elements can change over time. And this assessment can be informed by economic thinking. New arguments and new understandings develop; the job of the Court is to reconcile these with the principles underlying the earlier rulings. That is precisely how the law develops. The Courts' antitrust case law is based on the identification of dominance (i.e. market power) and abuse (i.e. practices that could harm competition). This provides a valuable framework for our decision making; it is far from being a straightjacket as the underlying concern is always the identification of harm to competition. 7

Consequently, if the Commission carries out a detailed analysis of practices so as to determine whether or not they harm competition, the Court should understand and, I would hope, support such an approach. 2.3 Intel, France Telecom and Deutsche Telekom This support was demonstrated in the France Telecom predation and Deutsche Telekom margin squeeze cases, and we are waiting to see how it will play a role in the Court's upcoming judgment in the Intel case. Almost two months ago, the ECJ also upheld the Commission's prohibition decision on Deutsche Telekom for abusing its dominant position through margin squeeze. This case is significant in that the Court endorsed the "as-efficientcompetitor test" used by the Commission. The Court explicitly stressed in that case the need to determine whether the practice leads to anti-competitive effects, concluding that the practice of the company constituted an abuse to the extent that it had an exclusionary effect on competitors who are at least as efficient, to the detriment of consumers interests. This is fully in line with our Guidance paper on exclusionary abuses. Last year the ECJ upheld the Commission's predation prohibition decision in France Telecom, confirming that recoupment was not a necessary part of a showing of predation. Leaving aside the question of recoupment of loss, I would note that the relevant question is one of demonstrating likely consumer harm as we seek to do in any abuse case, and there can be multiple ways of doing that. Indeed, the Court explicitly referred to our effects based analysis, opening the door to continued use of that analysis in the future. Intel is perhaps the leading example of our implementation of the thinking underlying our Enforcement Priorities guidance in Article 102 cases. In particular, the case examined whether the conduct at hand was capable of excluding a competitor as efficient as the dominant company. 8

2.4 Tomra and the principles of the Guidance paper on exclusionary abuse Some have contrasted this effects-based approach with the General Court's ruling in Prokent/ Tomra. But again I do not think that such a contrast would be a fair reflection of the Tomra ruling. I believe that on the facts of the case, the Court supported the Commission's analysis, which went beyond showing that effects were likely to occur, and showed that they had in fact materialised. There are elements in the judgment that both support the earlier case law taking a view that certain types of conduct are in general illegal, and at the same time show that the Court is sensitive to an effects-based approach. For example, the Court paid particular attention to the Commission's analysis of the structure and characteristics of the markets, the position held by Tomra and its competitors, the size of the customers, the development of demand, the coverage and duration of the contracts, and the "suction effect" of the rebate schemes. Alongside the "as-efficient-competitor-test", such factors are identified in our Guidance as important for the assessment of conditional rebates. And these elements were clearly perceived by the Court as relevant and supportive of the solidity of the Commission decision. Speaking in broader terms, I think that our Guidance Paper strikes a good balance in setting out our priorities for abuse of dominance cases. The Guidance is based on the principle that all firms - including those that hold a dominant position - are entitled to compete on the merits. What these firms cannot do is use their position to cut out competition, prevent innovation and ultimately harm consumers. There is no one test for determining the likelihood of harm, or which company is in a position to cause harm. It may be an electricity company that controls the price of your electricity at peak hours, or a quasi-monopolist software company that controls the operating system market at all hours. The long term harm to consumers of particular practices may be significant and justify intervention in both cases. 9

It is the likelihood of a negative impact on consumers a concern clearly recognised by the Court, including in the Tomra judgment that governs our enforcement policy. This will continue to be the case in our enforcement going forward. Conclusion This is where we are at today. Competition cases are an intricate combination of legal arguments backed by solid economic analysis. The interplay between law and economics has never been greater. And the Courts acknowledge this and welcome this interplay. I see this trend going forward and developing across competition law instruments. I hope to have set the scene for a fruitful discussion today. 10